CAIRN-INT.INFO : International Edition

1The multilateral trading system is now seriously threatened by the country which has been its main inspirer, the United States. The US position is focused on bilateral trade imbalances presumably resulting from unbalanced trade policies, but it is flawed. Not only does it make little sense given the existence of global value chains, but it also misses its target: what matters most are aggregate trade surpluses and deficits which depend above all on the differential between domestic investment and savings and little on trade policy.

2This Note first analyses the economic consequences of a full-scale trade war. Our estimates show that it would have a permanent effect on the GDP per capita of similar magnitude on the three major global powers (European Union, United States and China) around 3 to 4% of GDP, as big as that of the Great Recession of 2008-2009. The impact would be much more damaging for small countries. By contrast, the European Union is partly protected by the size of its internal market. In addition, the short-term effects would be even greater because of the negative supply and demand shock that the global economy would be subjected to. For this reason, the European Union must engage resolutely in a strategy of defence of trade multilateralism.

3We recommend combining the adoption of firm and credible retaliatory measures in response to the current attacks with an offer of multilateral or plurilateral negotiations on legitimate issues: macroeconomic imbalances, institutional design of disputes settlement at the World Trade Organization (WTO), reciprocity of commitments and updating of rules on subsidies, state-owned enterprises and intellectual property rights. However, considering now difficult plurilateral and multilateral negotiation with the US Administration are, Europe needs a plan B. In the short term, this requires, for instance, coordinating a club of countries in order to identify and implement strategies to circumvent US blocking of the WTO at the Appellate Body level.

4In addition, we recommend pursuing an ambitious policy of trade agreements. The expected economic gains are modest. But trade agreements can play an additional role of “insurance policy” in case of full-scale trade war and can be used to leverage on other non-trade issues. Therefore, these agreements should change and address two main concerns about globalisation: environmental protection with the issue of global warming and problems related to tax evasion and optimisation.

5We therefore recommend making the signing of a trade agreement conditional upon the adoption of the OECD’s action plan to combat erosion of the tax base and the implementation of the Paris Climate Agreement. We put forward progressive monitoring and sanction measures to ensure its effective implementation.

Globalisation, inequality and the rise of populism

6Economists widely agree that international trade is an important source of benefits in terms of welfare. These benefits arise from better allocation of resources, greater economies of scale and are reflected by lower production costs and prices as well as a greater variety of available products. There is a striking contrast with public opinion as several recent polls have shown (Printemps de l’Économie, 2018): 60% of French people have a negative opinion of globalisation and only 13% are favourable to a deeper trade openness. The French are more critical of trade integration than the Germans: 75% of the French and 57% of Germans are favourable to greater protection against foreign competition. This fear of openness to international trade is part of a more general distrust: 47% of Americans and 36% of French people want more to be done to protect them from today’s world. [1] At the same time, 68% of the French and 55% of Germans consider that globalisation increases social inequalities. Economists broadly share these concerns and point out that over the last thirty years increasing globalisation in trade has increased competition between markets, often at the expense of certain categories of workers in developed countries.

7Several empirical studies [2] have assessed the impact of increased imports from emerging and developing countries (mainly China) and the introduction of new technologies. While the increase in inequalities and the effects on wages and employment in developed countries can be partly attributed to the increase in imports from emerging and developing countries, these studies concluded, however, that technological change has played a more important role than trade. The studies [3] found that the regional employment areas most exposed to competition from Chinese imports – intensive in unskilled work – are the ones that have experienced the greatest decline in manufacturing jobs. In the case of the United States, however, the increases in manufacturing jobs from total exports are of the same order of magnitude as job losses brought about by imports from China so the net effect on jobs produced by trade in goods and services is probably globally very limited. [4]

8Finding 1. The destruction of jobs in the manufacturing sector and the increase in inequality are partly but not primarily due to the increase in trade.

9The estimates in this Note confirm economists’ view of international trade being a source of net benefits for countries that liberalise trade. Contrary to the view of the current US Administration, trade is a positive-sum game. These benefits are, however, unevenly distributed and create losers. The criteria and the arrangements for transferring gains from the winners to the losers of globalisation need to be reconsidered: with the possible exception of the Scandinavian countries, industrialised countries have failed to redistribute the benefits of globalisation. In this regard, the exclusive competence given to the European Commission in matter of trade policy justifies the implementation of a European instrument seeking to mitigate the negative consequences of trade liberalisation. While this instrument already exists in the form of the European globalisation adjustment fund, the tasks and resources assigned to it are manifestly insufficient. [5] It is certainly difficult to identify job losses specifically attributable to trade liberalisation, though it should not be an obstacle to European support for labour-market areas severely hit by unemployment. In addition, while trade globalisation requires resources, fiscal one especially, to redistribute its benefits and effectively support the most vulnerable sections of society, financial globalisation, through the mobility of capital, of production and of the taxable base – in particular that of large corporate groups – makes this redistribution more difficult. In practice, along with competition and tax optimisation (or even tax evasion) it puts an unprecedented pressure on our redistribution systems. Trade integration also acts as an incentive to this tax competition as it facilitates the relocation of production in response to tax advantages. For this reason, the political sustainability of globalisation calls for trade liberalisation issues to be linked with tax competition issues. This sustainability is now being challenged in most of the advanced countries, which are confronted with movements of opinion in favour of greater protection. However, a recent study shows that exposure to globalisation (as measured by the intensity of increased competition from Chinese imports) is not the only explanation for the rise in populism. In the countries mostly hit by the financial crises in the Euro area (2008-2013), economic insecurity and the perceived inability of governments to protect them effectively against such crises have added to globalisation as factors explaining the rise in populism. [6] There is also a parallel with the situation in the 1930s as recent work by economic historians shows that it was in countries that were unable (because of the gold standard) or unwilling to use monetary instruments to stimulate their economies that protectionist temptations were the strongest.

10Finding 2. This rise of populism is not only or even primarily fuelled by trade openness but rather by the sense of economic insecurity and growing inequalities.

11A repeated aim of the Trump Administration is to reduce bilateral trade deficits (in particular with China and Germany). This focus on bilateral deficits and surpluses rather than aggregate trade deficits and surpluses is flawed. Indeed, bilateral imbalances are largely linked to the respective industrial structures or value chain mechanisms. [7] Since a country’s trade balance is not determined by its trade policy but rather reflects its net savings, increasing trade protection has no impact on this balance, as the real exchange rate is adjusted, either by the nominal exchange rate or by inflation, if the savings imbalance persists. At the bilateral level, the argument is even more incongruous, given the poor economic sense of the bilateral balance in a context where supply chains are widely internationalised. However, the aggregate trade deficits and surpluses of large countries are a relevant issue since the global imbalances they generate may partly explain the 2008-2009 crisis. But these imbalances have little to do with trade policies (tariffs and trade agreements). There is no empirical correlation between trade balance and customs duties. [8] The current account is impacted by macroeconomic factors, such as fiscal policy, exchange rates, asset prices or productivity. In order to prevent the protectionist and populist contagion, governments should thus not hesitate to use macroeconomic instruments to support the economy in the event of a crisis. While the macroeconomic response worked relatively well in 2009 at the G20 level, it was then defective, in particular in the euro area. We conclude from this that the debate on current imbalances should be shifted from bilateral trade issues to multilateral macroeconomic issues. While discussions on this subject can take place within the framework of the G7 or G20, the three main players are undoubtedly the USA, the EU (and in particular the euro area) and China (G3).

Attacks on multilateralism and the uncomfortable position of the European Union

12Three recent decisions by the Trump Administration constitute attacks on multilateral rules. The first concerned the blocking strategy on the appointment of new judges to the WTO Appellate Body, which could jeopardise the dispute resolution system. The latter, considered as the “crown jewel” of the WTO, is essential for the proper functioning of the international trading system, which relies on its ability to enforce the rules accepted by its members. The second decision (March 2018) was to invoke the national security argument to apply – which was implemented for the European Union on 1st June 2018 – additional customs duties of 25% on steel imports and 10% on aluminium imports amounting to 6,4 billion US dollars in total. In this context, the EU rightly believes that it is entitled to respond to unilateral US measures affecting the European Union, Canada and Japan. The fact that these countries are close allies invalidates the national defence argument. The EU adopted retaliatory measures amounting to 2,8 billion euros (which could be extended by 2020 in case of WTO approval). The rejection by the European authorities of a voluntary export restriction – which would go against WTO rules – in exchange for an exemption from US tariffs is also part of the defence of multilateralism rules and an approach based on the rule of law. The third decision (March 2018) was to introduce tariffs of 25% on 50 billion US dollars’ worth of imports from China that the US Administration accuses of infringements regarding intellectual property protection threatening its innovation capacity; in June, customs duties threats of 10% on 200 billion US dollars’ imports were added.

13These decisions, taken as a whole, generate trade tensions, which are in themselves a source of uncertainty. One of the strengths of the WTO rules system at the outset is to reduce uncertainty about future tariffs. The current unpredictability will have a non-negligible impact, similar to their increase, not only on trade itself but also on investment. The European Union will therefore be a victim of this unpredictability, but the cost in terms of investment can be limited, if it keeps acting as a force for stability based on compliance with rules. However, it is in a unique position between China, with which it shares a commitment to the multilateral rules system, and the United States, with which it has several common grievances as regards China. These include steel (for which China has excess production capacity), intellectual property and the Chinese State’s role in managing the economy. The “Made in China” agenda is a concern for the European Union as much as the “America First” agenda of the Trump Administration.

14Finding 3. The current trade tension is a source of uncertainty and unpredictability that will have a negative impact on trade and investment.

Avoiding a trade war

What would be the effects of a full-scale trade war?

15The scenario of protectionist escalation at global level can no longer be ruled out. The global system based on non-aggression tariff commitments is fragile. The economic literature has shown that a large country, by making use of its market power, can impose customs duties to its advantage to lower the price of its imports or to encourage the relocation of industries to its territory. However, the current US trade aggression is more a response to political sector-based rather than economic-based motives. Due to value chains, most economists believe that the imposition of tariffs, in particular on intermediate goods such as steel and aluminium will be to the detriment of the US economy as a whole, even without retaliation. It may, however, lead to a series of retaliations and counter-retaliations. How much can world tariffs increase if we move from the current cooperative equilibrium to the non-cooperative equilibrium of a trade war? Two simulation studies indicate that tariffs would increase to 30 or 60 percentage points in trade war scenarios. [9]

16An estimate of the long-term impact of the most dramatic scenario was established with a 60 percentage points increase in tariffs on manufacturing goods (currently below 3% on average for the US and the EU) between the world’s major countries and restrictions on trade in services. [10] The European Single Market (post-Brexit) in this scenario remains intact and customs duties remain zero within the EU. Two scenarios are then considered: the first scenario, that of a full-scale trade war, where the new tariffs are applied everywhere except within the EU and the second scenario, involving a limited trade war, where they are not applied either within the EU or between countries that have signed bilateral trade agreements.

17The methodology we use exploits the most recent developments in academic literature described as “new quantitative trade models”. [11] It can be broken down into two stages: the first stage involves estimating the impact of tariffs and various types of regional trade agreements on trade based on historical precedents (data on international trade between 1948 and 2016). This makes it possible to simulate the impact of a change in costs on all trade flows between two partners. This exercise takes diversion effects into account: for example, an increase in customs duties between the United States and the European Union destroys trade between them but increases France’s trade with its European partners. The second stage involves translating this variation in a country’s trade openness into an impact on its real income. These simulations reflect the long-term impact of a trade war after adjustments in jobs and wages have been made: they thus underestimate certain short- to medium-term effects (see below).

18The “full-scale war” case shows that the permanent loss of GDP would be more than 4% for the European Union and more than 3% for France (see graph), i.e. an annual average loss of EUR 1,250 per capita in the EU and EUR 1,125 per capita in France. These losses are the direct consequence of a sharp fall in trade. For example, France’s trade outside the EU would fall by about 42%. The smaller and more open the countries are and the more they are affected with larger losses by the increase in production costs (through the destruction of value chains) and consumer prices as well as by the loss of markets. In a global trade war scenario, EU countries are partly protected by their membership of the European internal market. However, this fall of more than 3% in GDP for France should be compared to the loss of potential GDP that France suffered following the Great Recession of 2008-2009, which was estimated to be 2.2% by a recent OECD study. [12] This calls into question the US assertion that the EU and China would be the only losers in a trade war. A remarkable result of these simulations is that the losses of the three major trading powers (the United States, China and the European Union) are roughly equivalent, namely around 3% for China and the United States and 4% for the EU. For other open countries, these losses are much higher (more than 10% for Ireland, Canada, Switzerland, Mexico and Korea). Moreover, the literature has documented the long-term negative dynamic effects of an increase in customs barriers on long-term growth, in particular through the emergence of an administered economy that is not conducive to innovation and to the proper allocation of production factors. [13] Models integrating this decrease in productivity growth deriving from protectionism result in much higher permanent losses (at least doubled). [14]

The consequences of a global trade war, in % of GDP

figure im1

The consequences of a global trade war, in % of GDP

Source: Vicard V. (2018): “Une estimation de l’impact des politiques commerciales sur le PIB par les nouveaux modèles quantitatifs de commerce”, Focus du CAE, no 22, July.

19Finding 4. A global trade war would have a permanent effect of similar magnitude on the three major global powers (European Union, United States and China), to that of the Great Recession of 2008-2009.

20These estimates underestimate short- to medium-term effects since the macroeconomic and financial impact is not taken into account on this time scale. In the short- to medium-term, the sharp loss of purchasing power brought about by the increase in taxes worldwide should trigger a negative demand shock and a negative supply shock as well, due to the rise in the price of intermediate goods in global production chains. In addition, the fall in world trade would cause a major sectoral adjustment with large-scale job losses in exporting sectors that would not be able to be quickly offset by job creation in importing sectors, with a resulting sharp increase in unemployment. Several other mechanisms could have a negative impact: higher risk premiums in financial markets, increased uncertainty and possible tightening of monetary policy by central banks in response to inflationary pressures generated by tariffs. [15] The counter argument, however, is that the announcement of Brexit, which actually opened an era of uncertainty for the UK, did not, despite the recent slowdown in UK growth relative to its European partners, trigger the recession that some economists may have feared. Does this mean that the risks of a trade war, with uncertainties that go with them, are overestimated? We do not think so as, in the particular case of Brexit, the United Kingdom was able to benefit, at least in the short term, from a sharp depreciation of its currency, which dampened the shock. Since, in the event of a trade war, the shock would be global, exchange rate adjustments would reflect the relative effects on each country (smaller countries more affected than larger ones would see their currencies depreciate) but would not reduce the global shock itself.

21Other scenarios of more limited trade wars – such as the United States against China or the United States against the European Union – are also possible, even if they are more difficult to model. Assuming an additional tariff of 25% applied to all products traded between the United States and China, bilateral trade would be reduced by almost 60%, while Chinese exports to the European Union would increase by 10% and European exports to the United States would increase by 7%. [16] However, if the US were to impose a number of anti-dumping measures against Chinese imports, this would create a more damaging redirection of flows to the EU. [17] Another scenario is that of a bilateral agreement to the detriment of the EU. Although vague and not yet confirmed, the agreement of May 20, 2018 between China and the United States, through which China would commit to purchase more US goods, would have the same effect as the imposition of Chinese tariffs on imports of foreign goods other than from the United States. It is to be feared that this type of agreement will be proliferating, thereby fundamentally calling multilateralism into question.

Safeguarding multilateralism

22Given the strategy of an aggressive attack on multilateralism by the current US Administration in several domains such as trade (blocking of the Dispute Settlement Body, DSB and customs duties), environment (withdrawal from the Paris Agreement), and diplomacy (withdrawal from the Iranian Agreement), the European Union definitely requires to implement a defence strategy. Retaliations in proportion to unjustified US protectionist measures, together with a complaint to the WTO, are the only short-term options. To be effective, such retaliations should be coordinated with countries with which the EU has trade agreements (Canada, Japan, etc.). The purpose of these retaliations is to increase the cost of a unilateral protectionist policy for the non-cooperative country, since the suspension of concessions (i.e. the increase in customs duties) regarding a partner that violates its commitments is one of the fundamental principles of the WTO dispute settlement system.

23Recommendation 1. Make the protection of multilateralism the European Union’s priority. In the short term, the European Union should coordinate with its main trading partners the adoption of firm, proportionate retaliations in response to attacks on multilateralism.

24Furthermore, it is necessary to try to escape the political deadlock into which the US Administration is pushing its partners by putting on the table a proposal for multilateral negotiations regarding macroeconomic imbalances (see above) and WTO rules to adjust them to new economic and social realities. As regards the issue of the dispute settlement mechanism within the WTO, the EU could make an offer of negotiations to reform the current practice allowing DSB Appellate Body judges to continue the examination of cases for which they are responsible beyond the end of their mandate. However, it is not appropriate for the Appellate Body to challenge the power to interpret agreements. This is a demand by the United States so as not to encroach on the sovereignty of Member States. This would jeopardise the system as a whole since the judges’ interpretation is essential, given that no agreement is comprehensive or unambiguous.

25The European Union should also play a leading role in proposing discussions on rules at plurilateral level. Beyond the complaints on formal matters, several Member States have complaints or the substance of rules, in particular when it comes to ensuring fair competition and taking the specific features of the Chinese economy into account. While the US trade deficit argument has no economic consistency (see above), there remain two substantive issues on which serious negotiations are a priority: the reciprocity of commitments, given the differences in the level of development, and the updating of rules on subsidies and state-owned enterprises.

26Differences in countries’ revenue levels are currently only considered through special and differential treatment, based on the self-reported distinction between three categories: developed, developing and least developed countries. While China, the world’s largest exporter of goods, is still considered a developing country, rethinking is needed to make this differentiation more gradual by replacing, for example, self-declaration by a system based on objective criteria. As regards updating the rules, the fundamental problem is to ensure that they allow us to face competition from China on an equitable basis. In their current form, they are not suited to Chinese industrial policy, which massively favours strategic sectors through a combination of instruments (subsidies, input prices, credit and land allocations, trade relations with public or state-influenced companies) [18] that distort competition to the detriment of its partners bound by European and multilateral rules. The European photovoltaic panel sector, for example, was not able to withstand heavily subsidised Chinese competition. Updating the rules implies both defining and limiting the available instruments, the information relating to them and the responses that partners can make to protect themselves (in particular, anti-dumping and anti-subsidy measures). To overcome blockages associated with the consensus rule, plurilateral negotiations, bringing together a critical mass of member countries, are the most credible way forward. E-business, moreover, is another issue on which such an approach would be welcome, given the virtual absence of rules in this area.

27Recommendation 2. At the European level, offer plurilateral negotiations to change the WTO’s functioning and rules: operation of the DSB, reciprocity conditions given the differences in the level of development and rules relating to subsidies, state-owned companies and intellectual property rights.

28In the event of a persistent refusal or blocking by the current US Administration of the negotiating offers put forward by the European Union, which seems to be the most likely scenario today, the EU should adopt an alternative short-term “damage limitation” strategy. The EU and its partners then need to identify and analyse all possible strategies for circumventing the US WTO blockage, and even begin implementing them. For example, in order to circumvent the US blocking of the DSB in the short term, the EU could federate a club of countries, excluding the Americans, that would commit not to go to the Appellate Body in the event of appeals filed before the WTO.

29Recommendation 3. If it is not possible to break the US blockage of the WTO, federate a club of countries to identify and implement a bypass strategy.

What role for trade agreements?

30Following the failure of the Doha Round negotiations in July 2006, the major trading powers began to consider a shift in their trade policies towards bilateralism or regionalism. This was in particular the case of the European Commission which, while reasserting its commitment to the multilateral system, has considered that it was necessary to relaunch negotiations on new generation free trade agreements (FTAs) [19] with its main trading partners. This was done “while ensuring that the new FTAs would be a stepping stone and not an obstacle to multilateral liberalisation”. [20]

31Trade agreements essentially institute a reduction in trade barriers between a limited number of partners. They are by their very nature discriminatory and thus constitute an exception to the fundamental principle of the multilateral system of non-discrimination towards trading partners, as allowed by GATT Article XXIV (subject to compliance with specific rules). In terms of economic efficiency, these preferential agreements represent a “second best” situation combining a positive trade-creating effect (through the elimination of customs barriers between the countries signing an agreement) with a negative effect through the risk of trade diversion detrimental to the countries excluded from such a preferential agreement (which may ultimately also have a negative effect on the participating countries). Typically, the risk of trade diversion increases with the level of tariffs applied to non-preferential WTO partners: when these tariffs are low, the level of preference and therefore the level of discrimination is low. Positive effects prevail when trade agreements are of the “deep” type, with agreements going beyond areas already covered by WTO rules.

Who are the winners with trade agreements?

32The economic impact of recent or future agreements can be estimated by analysing the effects of past trade agreements. This analysis is based on the same methodology used to estimate a trade war (see above). The estimated benefits for the European Union of an agreement with Japan would thus be 0.07% of GDP assuming that this agreement corresponds to the “average” of past agreements (table). This method is also applied to Switzerland and the United Kingdom (box), comparing the current situation with the theoretical case of these countries no longer having a preferential trade link with the EU. For the main possible agreements, the economic benefit for France is between 0.03 and 0.23% of GDP (between 10 and 79 euros per capita), i.e. of the same order of magnitude as that for the EU as a whole. While these benefits may appear small, they are not very different from the benefits estimated by the OECD on other structural reforms in France. [21] The size of the benefits varies from one EU country to another primarily in proportion to the intensity of their trade relations with the partner concerned, hence the higher figures for Ireland with the United States. The countries having the greatest benefits in proportion to their size are those that are relatively small and geographically close. Switzerland is the most extreme case. Its benefits of a trade agreement are thirty times greater than that of its partner (EU). The large size of the European Union therefore creates a significant asymmetry: even if in absolute terms the economic benefits to be expected from an agreement are often close between the European Union and its partner, [22] they are much higher as a proportion of GDP for the outside country than for the EU. The small country benefits strongly from access to a large market while the advantage of access to a small market is small for the EU. [23] The use of this bargaining power in past EU agreements is not obvious as regards tariffs, where the practice has been to dismantle them symmetrically, with the exception of a few sensitive agricultural products. It is clear, however, in the regulatory field within which the EU imposes its framework to a large extent in trade negotiations. For example, European Union trade agreements systematically include detailed articles on public procurement and geographical indications. Recent agreements (with the exception of the one with Japan) also include the International Court System for Settlement of Investment Disputes.

Benefits associated with European Union trade agreements, as a % of GDP per capita

tableau im2
Canada Japan Switzerland United States Brazil China India Russia Countries for which an agreement already exists Countries for which there is no agreement; the benefits shown are potential benefits Countries outside the European Union Canada 0.41 0.00 0.00 – 0.06 0.00 – 0.01 0.00 0.00 Japan 0.00 0.23 0.00 – 0.01 0.00 – 0.01 0.00 0.00 Switzerland – 0.01 – 0.01 3.16 – 0.06 – 0.01 – 0.03 0.00 – 0.02 United States – 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.26 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Brazil 0.00 0.00 0.00 – 0.01 0.32 0.00 0.00 0.00 China 0.00 0.00 0.00 – 0.01 0.00 0.22 0.00 0.00 India 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 – 0.01 0.26 0.00 Russia 0.00 0.00 0.00 – 0.02 0.00 – 0.02 0.00 1.22 European Union and Member States European Union 0.03 0.07 0.11 0.26 0.04 0.28 0.04 0.12 Germany 0.03 0.10 0.19 0.31 0.04 0.44 0.04 0.14 Spain 0.02 0.04 0.05 0.14 0.05 0.17 0.03 0.05 France 0.03 0.05 0.08 0.23 0.03 0.20 0.04 0.04 Luxemburg 0.03 0.03 0.35 0.68 0.00 0.08 0.00 0.11 Italy 0.03 0.03 0.11 0.16 0.04 0.18 0.03 0.09 Ireland 0.13 0.16 0.20 1.48 0.06 0.27 0.03 0.11

Benefits associated with European Union trade agreements, as a % of GDP per capita

Source: Vicard V. (2018): “Une estimation de l’impact des politiques commerciales sur le PIB par les nouveaux modèles quantitatifs de commerce”, Focus du CAE, no 22, July.

The “insurance” dimension of trade agreements

33The current context of protectionist tensions and of threats on multilateralism is bringing about a profound change in the scope of trade agreements. While the multiplication of such agreements is likely to be at the expense of multilateralism, they may also represent, for the European Union, an “insurance policy” in the event of a full-scale trade war with the disappearance of the WTO. Such a trade war scenario in which tariff increases do not apply to partners [24] with which the EU has existing or ongoing trade agreements has been tested. This “insurance policy” strategy is effective as it reduces trade war losses for the EU and its Member States by one third (see graph). Similar results have been observed in recent empirical studies that show that trade agreements, by reducing uncertainty on future demand, act like an insurance policy for exporting companies. During the 2008-2009 recession, exports thus fell less among countries that had signed a trade agreement. [25] In addition, preferential agreements signed by the EU have a negative impact on countries that are not included in the trade agreement: this is the case of the United States that are harmed by the EU-Canada trade deal. These side effects of trade agreement are not what motivate countries to sign them but could also be interpreted as retaliatory measure against those who attack multilateralism.

34Recommendation 4. The European Union should continue to negotiate trade agreements both for the conventional economic benefits they provide and also for the “insurance policy” role they can play in the event of a full-scale trade war.

35However, these agreements need to be part of a new approach consistent with the European Union’s non-trade objectives such as environmental protection or tax cooperation.

Why include objectives other than trade objectives in trade agreements?

36The primary objective of the European construction was, through the integration of economies, to prevent the return of the conflicts that had ravaged the continent. The current US offensive puts this political dimension of trade relations back at the centre-stage of the debate, since the attacks by the US Administration go well beyond trade and challenge the transatlantic political relationship. The purely economic objective of international trade remains, of course, legitimate and the EU’s primary objective should be to safeguard these benefits. What about the new trade agreements? As shown in previous simulations, the pure economic benefits expected from trade agreements are now relatively modest except in three cases: a full-scale trade war where they can play an insurance policy role, the future agreement with the UK (see box) and for small countries. Our position is therefore that beyond the conventional efficiency benefits, other dimensions of these agreements must be included. Two issues seem essential as they are at the centre-stage of concerns about globalisation: the environment with the issue of global warming and taxation with the question of tax evasion and optimisation.

37The introduction of some non-trade matters is not completely new. It is reflected both in the inclusion of chapters on social, environmental and, more generally, sustainable development issues in the European Union’s trade agreements: the most recent agreements thus go well beyond areas already covered by WTO agreements (“deep” agreements).

38Two main reasons can be given for including non-trade matters in agreements. They may primarily respond to a set of policy preferences (on environmental or fiscal issues). Trade as a lever can facilitate cooperation in these areas, and the more intense the trade the more effective the cooperation.

39The steps taken to combat climate change provides a striking illustration of this: while the perfect example of the greenhouse effect externality makes international cooperation essential, this area offers little incentive for reluctant partners to cooperate. Indeed, it was reasoning based on the contrast between the negotiating capabilities in these two areas that led Nordhaus (2015) to propose using the threat of a tariff as a mechanism to encourage countries not included in a climate change agreement to join it. [26]

40On a more economic note, the second reason is the complementarity between trade policy and other areas of public policy intervention. Indeed, the adoption of demanding regulatory policies entailing additional costs compared to partner countries is likely to have trade consequences that are all the greater as trade barriers are low. This distorts comparative advantages which become more fiscal and environmental than productive. When it comes to putting a price on carbon emissions, the term leakage effects is used to refer to the loss of effectiveness of this type of policy associated with the relocation of some polluting production to countries where climate policies are less restrictive.

How is this done?

41Implementation procedures must be chosen carefully. Firstly, it is preferable to focus on an approach based on minimas and guarantees. This ensures consistency and sets limits, while preserving the freedom of action of partners. This has moreover long been the preferred approach on the social dimension of trade agreements, in particular based on requests for the application of International Labour Organisation (ILO) agreements, or in the environmental field through related multilateral agreements, which now have to include the Paris Agreement.

42Secondly, the objective of effectiveness calls for a combination of cooperation and enforceable commitments from the outset of agreements. These commitments may be a useful addition as long as they can be based on verifiable criteria, although this is most often difficult in social and environmental areas, where the margins for interpretation of commitments and their implementation are broad and difficult to measure. While some areas, such as taxation, are more suited to this, the European position remains weak due to its lack of internal coordination.

43Thirdly, to make non-trade clauses enforceable, it is best to establish in agreements that non-compliance may give rise to a trade response, even in the absence of proof of trade damage. The clauses concerning the motor vehicle sector in the EU/Japan agreement provide a useful example in this respect: a special safeguard measure allows the EU to reintroduce tariffs in this sector if Japan does not fully comply with its regulatory commitments to remove non-tariff barriers. While these provisions remain in the strictly trade field, they are an example of the parallelism established in the agreement itself between tariff and non-tariff concessions. Another example is the Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement (TPP), which was explicitly linking US trade benefits to Vietnam’s commitments on trade-union freedom and workers’ rights. Traditionally, the settling of trade disputes has been based on the principle of suspensions of concessions (e.g. tariff increases) being able to be taken to compensate for damages suffered as a result of nonconforming practices of partners. These examples show that it is possible to move towards a new system in which suspensions of concessions could respond to the lack of compliance with non-trade commitments (not covered by the WTO), even if no direct economic damage results. This would greatly facilitate dispute resolution.

Which post-Brexit trade agreement with the UK?

Various scenarios for the European Union’s trade relations with the United Kingdom have been simulated to estimate their long-term impact. The comparison is made against the current situation where the United Kingdom is still a European Union Member State:
  • The absence of a formal agreement that would involve relations governed by the “WTO’s” most-favoured-nation status;
  • A standard trade agreement similar to the one signed with “Canada”;
  • A deeper bilateral free trade agreement such as the one with “Switzerland”;
  • A “Norway” type Single Market access agreement.
The graph shows that the more ambitious the simulated agreement is, the more limited the Brexit-related losses are. The impact on France of the absence of a preferential agreement with the United Kingdom (– 0.3% of GDP per capita, or around more than EUR 100 per person) is not negligible, but it is much smaller than for the United Kingdom itself (around – 3%, or slightly more than EUR 1,000 per person) or for small countries that are highly dependent on their relationship with the United Kingdom such as Ireland or Luxembourg. [a] For the European Union, the effect of a lack of agreement would lead to a 0.8% reduction in GDP per capita (or EUR 260 per person).
These figures are fully in line with those obtained in other empirical studies. [b] In all cases, they conclude that the consequences of a “hard” Brexit are three to four times greater than those of a more optimistic scenario.
The future trade agreement with the UK will be exceptional in many respects and could set a precedent for new type agreements, giving centre-stage to fiscal, competitive, environmental and social issues. In this respect, the myriad of bilateral agreements with Switzerland, which are a product of history but which create a number of institutional problems (static agreements, very partial consideration of State aid, question of the dispute settlement body) clearly appears to the European Commission as a counter-model. The United Kingdom’s geographical position and initial situation (as a member of the Union) are such that an agreement should probably lie between full access to the Single Market and a Canadian-style agreement.

Scenarios of the consequences of the future post-Brexit agreement, as a % of GDP per capita

figure im3

Scenarios of the consequences of the future post-Brexit agreement, as a % of GDP per capita

Source: Vicard (2018), op. cit.
However, the economic implications are different due to the UK’s proximity. Unlike Canada, it could attract companies to its territory through an aggressive industrial and fiscal policy, and benefit from access, even imperfect, to the Single Market. The level ambition in terms of integration of the agreement between the European Union and the United Kingdom must thus be directly linked to the level of ambition of the mechanisms guaranteeing a level playing field [c] between the two partners; in particular as regards State aid [d] and a dispute settlement mechanism. However, there are a number of challenges. On the one hand, the European Union is faced with its own contradictions in these negotiations, since this level playing field has not been reached within the European Union on the issue of the taxation of corporate profits, [e] even if the use of State aid rules has enabled progress. [f] On the other hand, while the form this monitoring of the rules is to take is crucial, it has yet to be determined at this stage. For example, while the establishing of an independent domestic State aid monitoring authority would be welcome, it would not be sufficient in the event of disagreement as to what constitutes such aid. It is not clear whether the decisions taken by the Directorate-General for Competition on Apple’s undue tax advantages in Ireland, for example, would also be taken by an independent British authority.

44Fourthly, the Union must determine the desirable status for non-trade clauses. Should they be included in agreements or should trade preferences be made conditional on compliance with specific agreements (e.g. on sustainable development or tax cooperation)? Since trade agreements are part of a wider set of external actions and trade is a tool rather than an end in itself, linking them with other separate specific agreements would be more consistent than including multiple issues within trade agreements. However, complex legal and practical issues are involved, as was seen, for example, in the Schubert report (2017) [27] proposing a bilateral climate agreement between the European Union and Canada. Indeed, since the agreements include clauses related to investment, taxation or the environment, the Member States must be associated with their adoption, [28] as the Union strictly speaking loses its exclusive competence associated with trade.

45Recommendation 5. Adjust trade agreements to ensure that trade goes beyond purely economic issues. Prefer an approach of minimas and guarantees and combine cooperation and enforceable commitments through safeguard clauses or other explicit mechanisms.

Trade agreements and tax cooperation

46Tax instruments other than customs duties may have an impact on trade terms. This may be the case for corporation tax, which is ultimately borne in part by consumers and workers in open economies. [29] A tax advantage that would specifically benefit an exporting sector can be considered as an export subsidy whose trade distorting effects can be compared to those of customs duties. To be sure, the WTO has a binding instrument regarding direct taxation with the agreement on subsidies and compensatory measures, which makes it possible to impose trade sanctions on countries that use taxation to give their companies a competitive advantage. [30] However, as this rule only applies to the strict area of trade and cannot be applied with regard to tax incentives for investment, the WTO rules need to be changed to better take into account the issue of subsidies (see above).

47In the tax area, however, States oscillate between defending their sovereignty and acting within a multilateral or regional framework to avoid the erosion of their tax bases and to protect themselves against unfair competition practices. [31] This is a primary difficulty for the European Union, where tax optimisation issues arise within the Union itself, with countries (often small ones) that are also the main beneficiaries of trade agreements and of the European integration itself. Moreover, due to the short distance, the initial regulatory situation and the presence of a trade agreement, the more trade is integrated between two markets the closer the link between trade and taxation. Companies are indeed more mobile in a more integrated area, i.e. it is easier to relocate in one market for tax attractiveness reasons and then re-export to another. This dimension must therefore be included in trade agreements with close partners, such as the United Kingdom (see box). While there is now a standard article in the “financial services” section of European Union trade agreements which stipulates “proper fiscal behaviour” (steps taken to combat tax evasion, etc.), this does not imply any binding legal commitment (as they are only “best efforts” commitments) and is not present in all agreements. While it seems difficult to be very specific in the tax provisions associated with a trade agreement, compliance with the OECD codes of good practice and the BEPS (Base Erosion and Profit Shifting) action plan within a multilateral framework ought to be included as an integral part of future agreements. [32]

48Recommendation 6. Make the signing of a trade agreement conditional upon the adoption of the OECD’s BEPS action plan to combat erosion of the tax base. Put in place gradual control and sanction measures to ensure its effective implementation.

The environmental dimension

49The environment has a long history in European Union agreements; through the pillars of cooperation and, since the agreement with South Korea, through the chapters on sustainable development. However, the importance of the subject and its links with trade issues calls for renewed efforts, all the more so as the climate has thus far been conspicuously absent from the agreements signed. [33]

50Existing European Union agreements that include a chapter on “Trade and sustainable development” already implicitly imply compliance with the Paris Agreement through the commitment to comply with international multilateral climate treaties. It would be desirable for compliance with the Paris Agreement to become an explicit sine qua non condition of future EU trade agreements, as is already the case in the agreement with Japan and in the renewal of the agreement with Mexico. This would mean, on the one hand, that the Union makes it a prerequisite for the signing of trade agreements and, on the other, that it makes the full application of the agreements conditional upon compliance with the Paris Agreement. The benefit of certain trade preferences could be conditional upon the proper implementation of the commitments in the Paris Agreement: the market access conditions (customs duties and preferential tariff quotas) would then be the most favourable when the partner fulfils its commitments, but would be less so (within the limits of the conditions under the most-favoured-nation clause) if they are not fulfilled. Such a mechanism would create a tangible incentive for both the partner and the European Union to fulfil its commitments.

51Recommendation 7. Make the ratification and implementation of the Paris Climate Agreement a prerequisite for signing a trade agreement with a partner. Make the full application of trade preferences conditional upon compliance with climate commitments, in accordance with explicit provisions.

52Faced with the aggressive attack on multilateralism by the current US Administration, the European Union must put in place a forceful strategy. It should take the lead in proposing multilateral negotiations on the WTO’s functioning and rules in order to adapt them to the new economic and social realities. It should continue to negotiate trade agreements that act as insurance policies, while linking them to objectives other than trade.

The authors would like to thank Jean Beuve, CAE Scientific Advisor, who followed up this work, and Amélie Schurich-Rey, Samuel Delpeuch and Louis Vedel in the permanent CAE team who assisted them. They also thank Vincent Vicard (CEPII) for the simulation work carried out within the framework of this Note. Finally, they thank Sandrine Gaudin, Secretary General for European Affairs (SGAE), Muriel Lacoue-Labarthe (Treasury Directorate) and Édouard Bourcieu (European Commission), as well as their colleagues, for the interviews and information provided.

Notes

  • [1]
    IPSOS (2017): La tentation de l’Île : le protectionnisme est-il la solution ? Cf. www.ipsos.com/fr-fr/la-tentation-de-lile-le-protectionnisme-est-il-la-solution.
  • [2]
    An overview of this literature is given in a recent WTO report; according to the cases studied, the opening up to trade is alleged to be responsible for 20% of job losses, see WTO (2017): World Trade Report 2017. Trade, Technology and Jobs.
  • [3]
    This is in particular the case for the impact of Chinese imports on the US manufacturing sector, see Author D.H., D. Dorn and G.H. Hanson (2013): “The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States”, American Economic Review, vol. 103, no 6; Malgouyres C. (2017): “The Impact of Chinese Import Competition on the Local Structure of Employment and Wages: Evidence from France”, Journal of Regional Science, vol. 5, no 3, pp. 411-441.
  • [4]
    Feenstra R., M. Hong and X. Yuan (2017): “US Export and Employment”, NBER Working Paper, no 24056.
  • [5]
    Provided with a budget of EUR 500 million per year when it was created in 2006, the resources of the European Globalisation Adjustment Fund were reduced to EUR 150 million a year in the 2014-2020 budget due to its under-use. For an analysis of the operation of the current system and proposals for reforms, see Claeys G. and A. Sapir (2018): “The European Globalisation Adjustment Fund: Easing the Pain from Trade”, Bruegel Policy Contribution, no 5.
  • [6]
    Guiso L., H. Herrera, M. Morelli and T. Sonno (2018): “Global Crises and Populism: The Role of Eurozone Institutions”, EIEF Working Papers Series, no 806.
  • [7]
    For example, Germany has an aggregate trade surplus (of EUR 244.9 billion in 2017) and has bilateral deficits with a number of Eastern European countries from which it imports intermediate goods. Gross bilateral deficits do not take into account the fact that the value of exported goods (e.g. from China to the US) represents not only the value added by Chinese companies but also the value of intermediate goods imported by China. This difference between gross bilateral deficit and added value is about 40% in the case of the United States/China.
  • [8]
    There is no robust international relationship between the level of trade protection and trade balance, see, for example, Gagnon J. (2017): “We Know What Causes Trade Deficits, Trade & Investment Policy Watch, Peterson Institute for International Economics, 7 April or Hufbauer G.C. et L. Zhiyao (2016): Free Trade Agreements and Trade Deficits. Trade and Investment Policy Watch, Peterson Institute for International Economics, 31 March.
  • [9]
    See Nicita A., M. Olarreaga and P. Silva (2018): “Cooperation in WTO’s Tariff Waters?”, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 126, no 3, pp. 1302-1338 and Ossa R. (2014): “Trade Wars and Trade Talks with Data”, American Economic Review, vol. 104, no 12, pp. 4104-4146.
  • [10]
    Vicard V. (2018): “Une estimation de l’impact des politiques commerciales sur le PIB par les nouveaux modèles quantitatifs de commerce”, Focus du CAE, no 22, July.
  • [11]
    See Mayer T., V. Vicard and S. Zignago (2018): “The Cost of Non-Europe, Revisited”, CEPII Working Paper, no 2018-06, April.
  • [12]
    Ollivaud P. and D. Turner (2015): “The Effect of the Global Financial Crisis on OECD Potential Output”, OECD Journal: Economic Studies, vol. 2014, p. 48.
  • [13]
    See, for example, Aghion P., A. Bergeaud, M. Lequien and M.J. Melitz (2018): “The Impact of Exports on Innovation: Theory and Evidence”, NBER Working Paper, no 24600, May; Berthou A., J.J.-H. Chung, K. Manova and C. Sandoz (2016): Productivity (mis)Allocation and Trade, Paper at the Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association; Blaum J., C. Lelarge and M. Peters (2016): “The Gains from Input Trade with Heterogeneous Importer”, Banque de France Working Paper, no 612, December.
  • [14]
    Sampson T. (2016): “Dynamic Selection: An Idea Flows Theory of Entry, Trade and Growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 131, no 1 February.
  • [15]
    For the first time in April 2018, the US Federal Reserve raised concerns in the “Beige Book” about the possible imposition of tariffs on manufacturing imports.
  • [16]
    Bellora C., S. Jean and G. Santoni (2018): “Un chiffrage de l’impact des mesures de protection commerciale de Donald Trump”, Lettre du CEPII, no 388, June.
  • [17]
    US anti-dumping measures increase imports from the targeted countries to the EU of around 13%, see Skoglund L. (2018): Evidence of Trade Deflection: Investigating the Impact of US Antidumping on EU Imports, Mimeo Sciences Po.
  • [18]
    See, for example Wu M. (2016): “The ‘China, Inc.’ Challenge to Global Trade Governance”, Harvard International Law Journal, vol. 57, no 2.
  • [19]
    The first of these agreements was entered into with South Korea and has been in effect since July 2011. Peru and Colombia followed on (joined by Ecuador in 2017), together with Canada, Singapore, Vietnam and Japan. Negotiations are still ongoing with MERCOSUR, Chile and Mexico, the latter two countries already having free trade agreements with the European Union dating from 2000 and 2002 respectively.
  • [20]
    European Commission (2006): Global Europe: Competing in the World, COM(2006) 567 Finals, October.
  • [21]
    OECD (2014): France. Structural Reforms: Impact on Growth and Options for the Future, OECD Note, 14 October.
  • [22]
    In the case of the EU/Switzerland agreement, the benefit is around EUR 19 billion for Switzerland and EUR 17 billion for the European Union.
  • [23]
    Asymmetry is also present in the future agreement with the United Kingdom, which at first sight gives significant negotiating power to the European Union (see boxed text).
  • [24]
    Canada, South Korea, Japan, Mexico, Norway, United Kingdom, Switzerland and Turkey.
  • [25]
    See Carballo J.R., K. Handley and N. Limão (2015): “Economic and Policy Uncertainty: Export Dynamics and the Value of Agreements”, NBER Working Paper, no 24368.
  • [26]
    Nordhaus W. (2015): “Climate Clubs: Overcoming Free-Riding in International Climate Policy”, American Economic Review, vol. 105, no 4, pp. 1339-70.
  • [27]
    Schubert K. (2017): L’impact de l’Accord économique et commercial global entre l’Union européenne et le Canada (AECG/CETA) sur l’environnement, le climat et la santé, Report to the French Prime Minister, 7 September.
  • [28]
    As stipulated by the European Court of Justice in its statement (2/15) of 16 May 2017 on the Free Trade Agreement between the European Union and Singapore.
  • [29]
    See, for example, Simula L. and A. Trannoy (2009): “Incidence de l’impôt sur les sociétés”, Revue Française d’Économie, vol. 23, no 3.
  • [30]
    See, in particular, the dispute between the United States and the European Union relating to foreign sales corporations. The question of export subsidies should be raised again in connection with the recent US tax reform, which provides in particular for lower taxation of income derived from intangible assets when they originate abroad (Foreign Derived Intangible Income).
  • [31]
    According to a recent estimation, up to 40% of profits of multinational corporations are transferred to low tax countries, see Torslov T., L. Wier and G. Zucman (2018): “The Missing Profits of Nations”, NBER Working Paper, no 24701.
  • [32]
    However, the idea put forward by some economists that trade sanctions can be used to force tax havens outside the European Union to change their practices does not seem realistic to us as these countries are only marginally dependent on international trade. For such countries, financial sanctions are likely to be much more effective.
  • [33]
    As pointed out in the Schubert Report (2017), op. cit.
Sébastien Jean
CEPII and INRA.
Philippe Martin
Sciences Po, Member of the CAE.
André Sapir
Bruegel and Université libre de Bruxelles (Brussels University, Belgium).
This is the latest publication of the author on cairn.
Uploaded on Cairn-int.info on 21/08/2018
Cite
Distribution électronique Cairn.info pour Conseil d’analyse économique © Conseil d’analyse économique. Tous droits réservés pour tous pays. Il est interdit, sauf accord préalable et écrit de l’éditeur, de reproduire (notamment par photocopie) partiellement ou totalement le présent article, de le stocker dans une banque de données ou de le communiquer au public sous quelque forme et de quelque manière que ce soit.
keyboard_arrow_up
Chargement
Loading... Please wait