CAIRN-INT.INFO : International Edition

1 Sociologists are the only social scientists to have focused on criminal achievement. Delinquency trajectories have been analyzed as life projects in which subjects seek to realize themselves in various ways: through skill, for Edwin Sutherland (1937); wealth for Robert Merton (1965); popularity or prestige for David Greenberg (Greenberg 1977; Rebellon and Manasse 2004); strength of character for Gresham Sykes (Sykes 1958; Preble and Casey 1969) and freedom for Jack Katz (1988). Patterns in criminal achievement are viewed as an outcome of social mobility mechanisms (Cuin 1993), and it is this understanding that gives classic (primarily American) criminal sociology its specificity and narrative unity.

2 The working hypothesis in American sociology from Sutherland to Daniel Bell was that under certain conditions, delinquency trajectories could account for upward social and occupational mobility patterns (Bell 1965; Cloward 1959). This hypothesis has not been demonstrated. On the one hand, professional delinquent paths show little in the way of “mobility.” Adler and Adler’s 1983 field study of 65 accomplished smugglers and dealers operating in a small American city on the border with Mexico (see also Adler 1993) suggests that delinquency trajectories show primarily lateral mobility. They note that with few exceptions, the split between high and low echelons of illegal substance selling reproduces delinquents’ original occupational positions. A variant of this thesis may be found in Holtzman (1983). The author examined the record of legal jobs held by a cohort of thieves and burglars. Surprised to see that the vast majority had conventional jobs, he developed the hypothesis that their delinquent activities offered all the features of a moonlighter’s job, in this case unskilled workers who could only “make ends meet” by working on the black market.

3 On the other hand, most research using self-report surveys has denied any direct influence of social class background on crime involvement (Tittle, Villemez and Smith 1978; Tittle and Meier 1990; Reiss and Rhodes 1961; Roché 2001), strengthening the thesis that social labeling mechanisms suffice to account for the “social composition bias” found in police files and prison populations. However, social scientists may have dismissed the effect of social class background prematurely. Wright et al. (1999) took a different approach, claiming that the absence of correlation observed in Tittle and Meier’s meta-analysis (1990) did not necessarily mean an absence of causation. They argued that social class and crime are not necessarily linked in linear fashion. Both ends of the social class spectrum could exert a positive influence on crime involvement through different causal sequences. Citing self-report surveys of delinquent teenagers and young adults, they first observed no apparent relationship between respondent’s social background and criminal participation (proportion involved in delinquent acts), offense frequency (number of crimes commited) or offense seriousness. But they then discovered that feeling of impunity and taste for non-conformity increased with each rung on the social ladder, a finding that explains how it is that delinquent behavior may actually increase with social position.

4 These results, counter to American criminologists’ standard opinion, are not the only ones supporting the class-crime relationship. Hagan, Gillis and Simpson (1985), taking inspiration from William Bonger’s Marxist study (1916), confirmed that social class background influences the relation between delinquent activities and differential family supervision of teenagers of both sexes: differences in delinquent behavior by sex are sharp at the higher end of the social scale but decrease in the mid-level classes and are very slight at the lower end. Furthermore, Grasmick, Jacobs and McCollum’s self-report survey of delinquency (1983) showed that perceived risk of arrest and assessment of its consequences varied inversely with social class background for the teenagers interviewed. Wright et al. (1999) found that delinquent behavior also varied as a direct function of relative deprivation and degree of family disorganization, these in turn varying inversely with social class background. These results corroborated those of McCarthy and Hagan (2004), who added questions on personal income and expenses in their self-report delinquency survey. They found that social background interacts with criminal propensity: every increase in personal income lowers the delinquent conduct of teenagers at the bottom of the social scale while having no such effect on teenagers who enjoy the resources of a more privileged social milieu. The analytic solution put forward by Wright and his colleagues is elegant but has two drawbacks: “psychologizing” social class turns it into a construct that can explain both A and its opposite; the conceptual scenario was developed a posteriori to account for an expected result—i.e., social background’s apparent non-impact on self-reported delinquency.

5 In this article we examine offending outcomes rather than processes (i.e., offense frequency or seriousness). Past research has not tried to investigate empirically why, with level of criminal activity held constant, some delinquents manage to obtain considerable gains whereas others do not. This is surprising since it was a central issue for Cloward (1959), who argued that attractive criminal opportunities were themselves socially stratified. This major flaw is particularly clear in Hobbs’ assessment (1995) of published research on “professional” delinquency from 1937 to 1993. Despite the importance that Sutherland and Cressey (1966) attribute to training in the professionalization model of criminal trajectories (see Dubar and Tripier 2005), none of the studies reviewed by Hobbs addresses this point. Only recently, in connection with a survey of the criminal activities of an inmate sample from three Canadian federal prisons, did Morselli, Tremblay and McCarthy (2006) actually put the question to respondents directly: “Among the persons that have influenced you in your life, is there one who introduced you into the criminal milieu and whom you think of as your mentor?” Their results suggest that mentors do play an important role (39% of inmates interviewed said they had had a mentor), and that criminal mentors exhibit the same characteristics as mentors on conventional labor markets. The age difference between mentors and protegés is considerable (11 years on average), and no respondent said he had had “more than one mentor,” a point that brings to light the special, privileged nature of that relationship. In support of the thesis that mentor training is helpful, the study shows that delinquents who had the “luck” to meet a mentor reported median criminal incomes ten times higher than those who had not, and had spent less time in prison than mentorless delinquents in the three years preceding their incarceration. Meeting mentors (which is likely to occur when the delinquent-to-be is between 18 and 20) probably does not explain why individuals get started in crime but rather how their trajectories develop or “mature.” The mentor role is not incentive (i.e., it does not encourage non-delinquents to become delinquents) but formative, ensuring that a motivated delinquent will become a “good”—successful—one. Mentors “profess” crime as a vocation and seem to play a crucial role in professionalizing delinquents.

6 It is hard to analyze delinquents’ professional mobility without measuring their criminal performance. Contemporary criminology has shown little eagerness to do so. With the exception of a few field studies (McCarthy and Hagan 2001), the only self-report delinquency surveys to question delinquents on their individual performance (in this case, the income they get from their illegal activities) were done in the 1970s on representative inmate samples. Respondents were asked to detail their delinquency trajectories, the nature of the illicit activities they had engaged in the 36 months prior to their incarceration, the episodes of freedom and detention and the pace or tempo of their criminal activities by type (Peterson and Braiker 1981; Chaiken and Chaiken 1982; Blumstein et al. 1986). It was not until 15 years later that researchers began listening to what prisoners themselves had to say about their criminal performance (Tremblay and Morselli [2000] analyzed a 1976 survey of 672 detainees; Robitaille [2004] examined a 1978 survey of 2,670 detainees). These new analyses suggest that the sentences being served by “less skilled” offenders were as harsh as those of their “more skilled” neighbors; that the “more skilled” were, understandably, more inclined to quit the conventional job market than the “less skilled”; that the highest-performing delinquents were also the ones most likely to reoffend after release from prison. Criminal achievement, then, is not fortuitous but “deserved.” Success increases in proportion to the care delinquents take in planning and organizing their crimes. Heavy alcohol use compromises criminal performance, whereas cocaine or heroin addiction does not. Lastly, offenders who abstain from violence obtain less from their criminal activities than those who show no such scruples.

7 This article examines the hypothesis that a delinquent’s social class background influences his pathway in crime. The delinquent practices studied here (car-theft, illegal substance trafficking, aggravated or violent theft, “ordinary” credit card or check fraud) may be described as “common crimes” accessible to individuals from any social class background. This hypothesis differs from Cloward’s (1959), which argued that chances of succeeding in crime were independent of chances of succeeding on the conventional labor market. It also differs from the thesis that access to conventional jobs is the main or only mechanism stratifying crime opportunities (i.e., business crime versus “ordinary” crime). On the other hand, our hypothesis has the virtue of combining two research traditions that have always ignored each other: specialists interested in delinquents’ social backgrounds are necessarily less interested in their professional trajectories, while specialists interested in delinquents’ professional trajectories have not been interested in their social backgrounds.

8 The article proceeds through five stages. The first section describes the conditions in which inmates were interviewed and the strategy used to piece together their life trajectories during the three years preceding the prison term served at the time of the interview. The second section presents our two major analytic variables—upstream, delinquents’ social background; downstream, their criminal incomes during the “window period.” The third section analyzes how offenders’ criminal incomes vary with their social backgrounds. The fourth section presents three mechanisms likely to have conditioned the observed relations between social background and criminal achievement: delinquents’ personal ambition or desire to “get rich”; their access to criminal education (meeting a “criminal mentor”); their choice of criminal activity/ies. The fifth section examines the effects of social class on the relative severity of the criminal courts. Though the “class-based justice” notion has been largely overshadowed, particularly in the United States, by study of skin color or racial discrimination, we pursue here a tradition of research initiated by Herpin (1977), Pires, Landreville and Blankevoort (1981) and Aubusson de Cavarlay (1985, 1987; see also Aubusson de Cavarlay et al. 1995), though from a different perspective and with a more circumscribed focus. All inmates interviewed for this study shared the same penal adversity (serving a federal term of two years or more) and presented the same self-reported criminal profile (common offenses). Our aim is to determine whether, with criminal record and type of criminal practices held constant, bad boys from “good families” have an advantage in the criminal courts and if so, by what means they secure this advantage.

Respondent Sample and Interview Procedure

9 Two hundred and sixty-two inmates in five federal penitentiaries [1] in the Montreal area were interviewed during the summer months of 1999, 2000 and 2001. While inmate surveys are usually self-administered and filled out by groups of inmates (Peterson and Braiker 1981; Chaiken and Chaiken 1982; Horney, Osgood and Marshall 1995), our interviews were conducted face-to-face, allowing interviewers (three male and six female students) to make sure that each question was correctly understood and to obtain sufficiently precise answers. To minimize memory errors, respondents who had been in prison for more than seven years were excluded—a screening precaution of limited use since the majority of respondents (76%) had been in prison less than two years. Average interview time was an hour and thirty minutes. The interviews did not focus on the prison term inmates were serving but on the 36 months preceding the moment that prison term began, what we are calling the window period.

10 Inmates were randomly selected from a list of prisoners physically present on the given day. Half the interviews were made in medium-security prisons (n = 123, or 47%) and half in minimum-security prisons (n = 123, or 47%). [2] In the medium-security prisons, interviewers were provided with rooms where prisoners usually meet with their lawyers. Each room had a telephone connected to various sections of the penitentiary and it was up to the interviewers to contact the inmates. In minimum-security prisons, the call for respondents worked somewhat differently due to residents’ freer movement. The easiest way to reach them was over the intercom system from a control post near the interviewing room. The order to go to the interviewing post was heard in each unit of the establishment, but as in the other prisons, the reason for the call was not indicated. Though 262 prisoners were interviewed, this study is based on a 195-interview sample: 45 respondents were disqualified because their criminal activities were not motivated by financial gain (sexual offenses, for example, dangerous driving, etc.) and another 22 for incomplete questionnaires.

11 The interview began with the usual introductions and guarantees of anonymity and confidentiality. Inmates could refuse to be interviewed (20% took that option); [3] they could interrupt the interview at any time and refuse to answer any question. The title of the questionnaire was deliberately vague: “Survey on inmates’ financial situation before current prison term.” Nonetheless, it was clear that the questions would bear on respondents’ licit and illegal income. We wanted to offer symbolic compensation for participation but the prison authorities vetoed that proposition.

12 To facilitate reconstruction of respondents’ lives during the three-year period, answers were transposed onto three 12-month calendars (on this strategy for contextualizing life stories, see Horney, Osgood and Marshall 1995; Freedman et al. 1988; Bradburn, Lance and Shevell 1987). Served prison time was the first piece of information put on the calendars. Respondents had to reconstruct their “prison trajectories,” indicating months in which arrests occurred, periods spent in prison, and months under probation, conditional release or in a “transition house.” The vast majority of respondents knew the exact entry and departure dates of their various stays in prison. The interviewer then went through a list of life events sufficiently important for most inmates to be able to indicate the months in which they occurred (if they did): death (s) of close relative (s) or friend (s), hospitalization (s), therapy program (s), suicide attempt (s), separation (s) or divorce, childbirth (s), job loss (es), significant money loss (es) and housing move (s) were all marked on the calendars. Legitimate work experience was then added to this first set of path markers. After specifying the three most important jobs held during the period, respondents were asked to indicate what months they had held them and their income for each month worked.

13 Delinquent activities were taken up last. [4] Respondents were asked first to indicate if they had engaged in various property offenses (aggravated theft, burglary, car theft, theft, fraud, con games, swindling) or trafficking on illegal markets (drug dealing and distribution, contreband, fencing of illicit goods, illegal gambling, loansharking, pimping). [5] After specifying the parameters for each of these activities (degree of planning, pace of criminal acts, average earning per offense, number of co-offenders implicated, most frequent targets, etc.), respondents were asked to indicate an estimate of their illegal gains (for a detailed analysis see Charest 2007).

Analytic Strategy

14 Interviewed inmates’ positions on the social scale were derived from the nature of their fathers’ jobs (or former jobs). Specifically, we used Nakao and Treas’ occupational prestige scale (1994) to group employment spheres into six categories: 1) liberal professions and management positions (manager, teacher, engineer, doctor, judge, architect); 2) technical jobs, sales, administration (IT specialist, civil servant, buyer); 3) service jobs (clerk, police officer, firefighter, restaurant owner); 4) “skilled” manual jobs (plumber, machine operator, welder, electrician); 5) “unskilled” manual labor (cleaning, truckdriving, delivery, unskilled construction work) and 6) farming, fishing, forestry jobs. These employment categories and the order they appear in differ very little from other occupational prestige scales used in Canada (namely Blishen 1958). Nakao and Treas’ scale was chosen primarily because it includes a wider, more contemporary array of occupations. Given the limited number of respondents in some categories (forestry and farming), we restricted our scale to four groups: 1) professionals and managers; 2) technical, sales and services; 3) skilled manual labor; 4) unskilled manual labor. To these four categories we added “jobless,” comprising all respondents whose fathers have been unemployed for most of respondent’s life (see Appendix for a presentation of fathers’ occupations).

15 Social position was found to be correlated with a series of other indicators of family’s socio-economic level. For example, 91% of professional and manager fathers were homeowners, against 48% of manual workers (the contingency coefficient, C. C., is 0.26, p < 0.001). Frequency of recourse to social assistance rises as social background declines (C. C. = 0.34, p < 0.001). Only 4% of professional families (one in 23) had received welfare at one time or another in delinquent’s life, as opposed to 42% of unskilled worker families. Moreover, the higher the occupational prestige, the more likely respondents’ fathers were to have subordinates working for them (C. C. = 0.35, p < 0.001). Number of employees for which father is accountable also varies proportionately with social status (C. C. = 0.49, p < 0.001). Social position also tallies with respondent’s personal assessment of family’s financial situation (r = 0.396, p < 0.001). Most respondent families did not seem to have experienced notable financial difficulty when inmates were young. More than 30% of respondents thought of their family situation as “well-off”; 49% as “within the average”; only 21% of respondents considered their family’s income below average.

TABLE 1

Inmates’ Fathers’ Occupational Categories

Occupation
category
N % % of Quebec
population
Prestige
rating
%
owners
%
employed
Jobless % on
welfare
Subjective
class (3
categs.)
Liberal professions,
manager
23 12 11 65 91 100 3.9 4 2.8
Technical, sales
and service
32 16 30 48 59 76 1.9 26 2.1
Skilled manual 56 29 19 43 71 66 1.7 18 2.2
Unskilled manual 78 40 32 30 55 45 0.9 42 1.8
Jobless 6 3 9 0 0 0 0 83 1.5
Total-Average 195 100 100 41 63 64 1.7 29 2.1
figure im1

Inmates’ Fathers’ Occupational Categories

16 Table 1 shows respondent number and proportion by father’s job category as well as occupational categories of male Quebeckers aged 55 and over (an age similar to respondents’ fathers’ ages). [6] We see that there are approximately as many sons of professionals, businessmen and managers in our sample as in the population at large: 12% versus 11%. At the bottom of the social scale (jobless fathers’ sons) the proportions are also similar: 3% versus 9%. Delinquents’ fathers are not proportionately more likely to be receiving unemployment or other welfare benefits than the Quebec population at large. However, poorer social backgrounds are overrepresented in our sample. While approximately 50% of male Quebeckers age 55 and over have jobs in the manual labor sectors (either skilled or unskilled), the figure is 69% for our inmate sample. Two-thirds are therefore of working-class background. The overrepresentation corresponds to underrepresentation of the middle classes, i.e., fathers working in technical, service or sales jobs. Nearly one-third (30%) of male Quebeckers work in these sectors whereas they account for only 16% of our sample. Despite these differences, there is significant social background diversity. The social composition of this inmate sample is similar to the one found in Zamble and Porporino’s 1988 study of federal prisoners in the Canadian province of Ontario, where 28% of prisoners were from middle-and upper-class backgrounds (professionals, managers, skilled white collar), 39% from the working class and 33% from the lowest classes (unskilled or unemployed).

17 To measure criminal incomes, respondents were first asked to indicate type (s) of criminal activity practiced in the window period, the frequency of activity for each type of crime committed and the average income per crime or transaction. Monthly and cumulative income during the 36 months was estimated by combining these three data. In the second section of the survey, we asked inmates for their own estimate of their illegal income for each month in which they were criminally “active” before incarceration (using three 12-month calendars). The two measures took into account months of respondent activity and inactivity, so that the “delinquent activity period” may be thought of as a constant. The correlation between these estimations is somewhat strong (0.52) though they require distinct intellectual operations (analytic for the first one and synthetic for the second). Discrepancies between estimations cannot be explained by interviewer’s sex or age, prison in which the interview took place, number of delinquent’s prison stays or time interval between interview date and start of the window period (Charest 2004). Reported incomes (the second measure) were generally more conservatives than estimated (or derived) incomes and were used as our main dependent variable. A logarithmic base transformation was ultimately applied for several distinct reasons: doing so normalizes income distribution (see, for example, Tremblay and Morselli 2000; Matsueda et al. 1992), corrects for differential perceptual discrimination across the income continuum (Tiberghien 1984), and reduces possible distorsion effects due to bragging or exaggeration. The correlation between logged reported and estimated incomes is almost perfect (r = 0.97).

The Effects of Social Class on Criminal Achievement

18 Social class background is positively related to criminal achievement measured by illegal earnings (r = 0.156, p = 0.026). What is true at the individual level is also true when individuals are grouped together (Table 2). The criminal revenues of offenders at the higher end of the social scale (sons of professionals and managers) are distinctively higher than those of the lower echelons; they average $170,000 over three years [2001 Canadian dollars], or $56,000 per year. As social position declines, so does illegal income. In the second echelon, average criminal income is only $42,000 ($14,000 per year). In the manual labor categories, sons of skilled workers (third echelon) made on average $30,907 from their criminal activities, whereas sons of unskilled workers (fourth echelon) made less than $17,000 ($5,600 a year). This gradual decline is reversed at the bottom of the social scale: jobless men’s and welfare recipients’ sons generally succeed better than delinquents at the center of the distribution (a result consistent with the hypothesis of Wright et al., 1999). Their criminal gains ($100,719, or $33,573 a year), while below those of delinquents from the privileged class, are far above those of “middle-” class delinquents.

TABLE 2

Real and Potential Licit Earnings and Actual Criminal Income (Geometric Mean) by Social Class Background

Father’s occupational category N Mos. of work
(% of mos.
of freedom)
Observed annual
legitimate
income ($)
Potential
legitimate
income ($)
Self-reported
annual criminal
income ($)
Professionals, managers 23 13 (45%) 10,253 30,584 56,399
Technical, sales and services 32 12 (34%) 12,638 30,640 13,939
Skilled manual 56 15 (46%) 8,524 29,903 10,302
Unskilled manual 78 13 (41%) 10,471 29,269 5,652
Jobless 6 10 (34%) 7,201 27,882 33,573
Total 195 13 (42%) 10,141 29,781 10,791
figure im2

Real and Potential Licit Earnings and Actual Criminal Income (Geometric Mean) by Social Class Background

19 What explains these performance inequalities? One scenario is that middle and upper class “bad boys” have relinquished advantageous legitimate employment income and therefore demand higher criminal compensation. As it turns out, legitimate income is fairly stable across social class backgrounds. Inmates’ hourly wages during the window period do not differ perceptibly from one class to another, suggesting that the quality of jobs held does not really differ with social background. [7] Most delinquents have jobs at the bottom of the occupational prestige scale. A possible alternative scenario: legitimate income of delinquents from the relatively privileged classes is just as low as others’ but they may be less motivated to remain in low-quality jobs. However, this scenario does not hold up since number of months at work does not vary across social class background. All respondents shared a pattern of sporadic participation in the conventional labor market (13 of the 36 months window period). Third scenario: while the actual performance of more socially advantaged offenders does not differ from other offenders’, they may believe that their earning prospects would be more enticing if they actually put their minds and social resources to criminal activity. This scenario too must be discarded: delinquents of middle- and upper-class background are just as likely to have dropped out of school. Though offenders from privileged social backgrounds do show higher average educational attainment (48% of them finished high school as opposed to 19% of the second echelon, 14% of the third and 13% of the fourth), few went beyond high school, meaning that educational differences are slight and unlikely to have an impact on the job market. [8] We estimated those “potential” legitimate incomes [9] (see Table 2, column 4) and found no correlation with respondent’s social status.

20 Offenders’ criminal achievement does not offer a reverse image of the licit earnings they have relinquished. It is not because members of privileged social classes have more to lose that they demand higher compensation from crime. There is yet another alternative scenario, however: offenders may not all have the same standards of achievement. A classic hypothesis has been that social class background affects delinquent’s aspirations or degree of ambition (Hyman 1965). Delinquents from relatively poor backgrounds seem ready to settle for more “modest” licit or illicit income. We included in our survey a question on delinquents’ monetary goals: “Do you agree or disagree with the following statement: ‘I want to make a lot of money’?” The results show a positive correlation between social class and desire for high financial returns (r = 0.157, p = 0.03), suggesting that aspirations are indeed influenced by social background.

Ambition, Social Capital and Criminal Occupations

21 We now examine the relevance of this last scenario. The aim is to model the series of processes by which delinquents from relatively privileged backgrounds obtain more successful trajectories than others. In this analysis, criminal income is the dependent variable, social class background the antecedent variable, respondent’s age the control variable, and ambition an “intervening” variable since social class may influence delinquents’ degree of criminal ambition. This study also explores the impact of social capital and criminal mentoring on offender performance (Morselli and Tremblay 2004; Morselli, Tremblay and McCarthy 2006) and incorporates a “professionalization” indicator into the model: presence or absence of a criminal mentor. Though these intervening variables both precede criminal performance, ambition is conceived as a relatively stable characteristic that precedes the encounter with a mentor. As previously mentioned, offenders are typically coopted by mentors at age 18 or 19. While it is true that social class influences mobility opportunities, we also need to account for delinquents’ criminal choices, especially the decision to pursue “entrepreneurial” or market activities [10]. Charest (2007) has shown that participation in such activities enables offenders to bring in attractive, stable incomes while incurring lower detection risk.

TABLE 3

Regressions of Combined Inmate Sample Criminal Trajectory Parameters (Performance, Training, Professional Choice) on Delinquents’ Social Class Background and Age

M1
Criminal
income
b
(beta)
M2
Ambitions
M3
Criminal
income
M4
Mentor
M5
Criminal
income
M6
Entrepre
neurial
crime
M7
Entrepre
neurial
crime
M8
Criminal
income
b
(beta)
b
(beta)
Exp (B)
(Wald)
b
(beta)
Exp (B)
(Wald)
Exp (B)
(Wald)
b
(beta)
Age –.067** –.040** –.058** .969+ –.055** .990 .996 –.054**
(–.360) (–.288) (–.309) (2.76) (–.290) (.361) (.045) (–.288)
Social class .228*
(.133)
.150+
(.117)
.172
(.099)
1.48**
(6.49)
.121
(.070)
1.31+
(3.44)
1.21
(1.59)
.097
(.056)
Ambitions -- - - .240*
(.179)
1.35*
(4.34)
.209*
(.155)
1.16
(1.46)
1.10
(.546)
.197*
(.147)
Mentor -- - - - - - - .593*
(.157)
- - 2.91**
(10.14)
.450+
(.119)
Entrepreneurial --
crime
- - - - - - - - - - - - .556*
(.155)
Constant 5.98** 5.75** 4.63** – 2.06 4.58** – 1.08 – 1.21 4.46**
R2 or pseudo R2 .153 .091 .165 .131 .184 .048 .118 .202
N 195 186 186 186 186 186 186 186
figure im3

Regressions of Combined Inmate Sample Criminal Trajectory Parameters (Performance, Training, Professional Choice) on Delinquents’ Social Class Background and Age

Note: **? < .01; *? < .05; +? < .10.

22 Model 1 indicates that offenders’ social class background improves their criminal performance (b = 0.228, p < .05). Criminal earnings also decline with age (b = –0.067, p < .01). This may be due to weariness (older delinquents are more “tired” or less active) or a self-selection effect (dynamic and successful delinquents may abandon their criminal careers more quickly). As hypothetized, three mechanisms may contribute to this class effect: aspirations or desire to obtain personal wealth (Model 2), training by a criminal mentor (Model 4) and participation in entrepreneurial crime (Model 6). Model 2 shows that ambition level is indeed modulated by social class background (b = 0.150, p < .10), and Model 3 that with individual desire to get rich controlled for, social class background effect on criminal performance vanishes (b = 0.172). Model 4 shows that delinquents from privileged social backgrounds are more inclined to seek out and find criminal mentors when they become young adults (b = 1.48, p < .01) and that the most ambitious delinquents are the ones most likely to attract mentors’ attention (b = 1.35, p < .01). Model 5 shows that when the effects of training (mentors) and motivation (desire to get rich) are taken into account, the direct effect of social class background on criminal performance likewise disappears (b = 0.121). Delinquents’ occupational choices also play a role. Model 6 shows that bad boys from the upper classes are more likely to opt for entrepreneurial crime (b = 0.131, p < .10). Mentors seem to be what tip the scales: when presence or absence of a mentor is controlled for, the social class effect on decision to engage in entrepreneurial crime disappears (Model 7). The last model provides a synthesis of the preceding analyses. Delinquents’ trajectories reproduce the social inequalities to be found among their fathers, and this reproduction is framed by three factors: delinquents from relatively privileged families manifest, from the outset, a relatively strong desire or will to “get a good return” on their illicit activities (b = 0.197, p < .05); they are more inclined to seek out and find criminal mentors who will provide them with useful training (b = 0.45, p < .10) and they are more inclined to choose entrepreneurial crime (b = 0.56, p < .01). These three factors have cumulative effects on performance but are also interdependent: ambition attracts the attention of mentors, who then guide ambitious delinquents into entrepreneurial crime.

Social Class, Sentence Leniency and Criminal Achievement

23 We might be tempted to believe that the most prolific, lucrative criminal careers are also likely to attract police attention and incur judicial severity. Preliminary inspection of our survey data indicate that prison sentences meted out inside the three-year study period were not influenced by delinquent’s degree of success. The most successful delinquents were not the ones most often sent to prison (r = 0.103, p = 0.15, n = 195) or for the longest time (r = 0.031, p = 0.67). The results are the same for sentences that inmates were serving at the time of the interview (see Table 4 for distribution of sentences being served by social class background). Offenders at the top of the income scale did not get longer federal sentences (r = –0.024, p = 0.77). If we isolate income for the last year of the calendar (assuming the current prison sentence derives from offenses committed that year), the relation does not improve (r = 0.004, p = 0.96). Sentence severity, then, is not directly proportionate to the gains delinquents obtain from their offenses.

24 However, labeling theory suggests that offenders with a middle and upper class background involved in “common” delinquency are more likely to obtain lenient rulings from criminal courts. For offenders with this social profile, the “lawyer’s role as a neutralization mechanism capable of extracting additional advantages for the accused is remarkable. We are not referring directly to the lawyer’s function but rather the structural, organizational, and ideological possibility of requesting or seeking out exceptional measures without discrediting oneself in the eyes of the other players (police, prosecuting attorney, judge, etc.)” (Pires 1983; Pires, Landreville and Blankevoort 1981: 333). This hypothesis, derived from a small number of interviews, [11] deserves a closer look.

TABLE 4

Inmate Respondent Profile: Offense Convicted of, Legal History, Lawyer’s Fees Paid out in most Recent Trial

Age Length
(severity)
of
sentence
(mos.)
Sentence
severity
relative to
offense
convicted of
Delin
quent’s
incarce
ration
history
Use of private law firm
Aver. Aver. Violent
crime
Proportion % who
paid
$
(aver.)
$ (total
aver.)
%
receiving
financial
support
% not
called upon
to
reimburse
anything
(standard
deviation)
(Median) (Homicides)
%
(average
number)
Liberal profs,
management
31
9.5
51 34
(4.3)
74%
(2.3)
70 43,825 33,390 31 40
(36)
Technical, sales
and service
31
8.6
63 50
(9.4)
59%
(2.5)
56 47,040 27,314 41 75
(48)
Skilled
manual
31
9.4
57 43
(8.9)
82%
(2.1)
54 36,643 19,630 31 67
(38)
Unskilled
manual
32
10.1
62 42
(3.6)
77%
(2.5)
55 18,015 9,865 35 59
(48)
Total 31
9.5
59.6 42
(6.2)
75%
(2.3)
56 31,599 18,104 34 62
figure im4

Inmate Respondent Profile: Offense Convicted of, Legal History, Lawyer’s Fees Paid out in most Recent Trial

25 Table 4 suggests a social class background effect on prison sentence length at both distribution extremes: an average sentence of 51 months (median 36) for wayward sons from the most affluent social class, and an average sentence of 62 months (median 48) for sons from the most disadvantaged milieus. Note that prior record indicators, likely to influence criminal courts (prior incarcerations, length of prior prison terms), do not vary by social class background. Average age of respondents is also similar from one group to the next, indicating comparable periods of exposure to the risk of incarceration.

26 Nonetheless, our data do confirm Pires, Landreville and Blankevoort’s hypothesis (1981): the higher a delinquent’s social class background, the more likely he (or his family) will hire a lawyer to defend him (column 5) and the more they are willing to pay for that service (columns 6 and 7). One third of delinquents receive family financial support for their legal expenses. This is often unconditional support: two-thirds of delinquents receiving it are not expected to pay it back. Interestingly, defendants from upper-class backgrounds are more likely than others to repay the money lent to them (60% as against 38% for the sample as a whole). Note that delinquents with the highest criminal incomes are also those who pay the most in lawyers’ fees—around $33,000, compared to the average of $18,000. These findings are perfectly consistent with the general argument that mobilization of legal resources increases with defendant’s social status (Black 1976: 11-36; 1989: 20-40). These findings also challenge conventional labeling research’s one-sided emphasis on rejection and exclusion (Cusson 1983).

27 Some findings reported in Table 4 are not easy to interpret because a number of factors have to be controlled for to isolate possible effect of social class background on court sentencing severity. First, we would expect that delinquents who spent the most in legal fees were those at risk of being incarcerated for long periods of time. Seriousness of charges should therefore be controlled for. Second, it is reasonable to assume that offenders will be more motivated to pay lawyers when the evidence against them is circumstancial or relatively weak (see Albonetti 1987 on the decisive effects of evidence “solidity” on trial results). We do not have a direct measure of the strength or weakness of respondents’ legal cases, but it is reasonable to assume that the money spent on lawyer’s fees measures the intensity of lawyer’s efforts to negotiate a sentence that will benefit their clients. The presence or absence of a specific social class background effect on sentencing severity is more likely to be revealed if money spent on lawyer’s fees is kept constant. Our working hypothesis, then, is that delinquent’s social class background only becomes an advantage when an authorized third party (i.e., the defense lawyer) is in a position to use that background “without discrediting himself in the eyes of the other court players.” To isolate the effect of social class on sentence severity, then, we conducted an analysis that took into account the parallel effects of charge seriousness, lawyer’s fees, age, prior incarceration history, criminal earnings and other characteristics (being head of household, having a conventional job).

28 Table 5 presents three analytic models. The first two conceptualize the effect of social class background on sentence severity. The third examines social class effect on a mechanism that plays a crucial role in the final determination of sentence severity, the use of a private defense lawyer.

TABLE 5

Regressions of Sentencing Severity (Months in Prison) and Lawyer’s Fees on Social Class Background, Offense Convicted of, Criminal Performance, Age and Other Characteristics

Sentence severity Lawyer’s fees
b beta sig b beta sig Age 0.13 0.025 0.713 0.13 0.026 0.692 Social class –3.52 –0.075 0.200 –5.82 –0.123 0.033 Incarcerationhistory 1.67 0.015 0.808 1.17 0.011 0.859 Violence 19.58 0.198 0.001 20.03 0.205 0.001 Homicide 111.48 0.550 0.000 104.78 0.526 0.000 Lawyer’s fees (x $1,000) -- -- -- 0.22 0.194 0.002 Mos.ofwork 0.37 0.100 0.096 0.32 0.087 0.138 Dependentchildren 2.51 0.026 0.677 0.75 0.008 0.898 Criminalincome 0.06 0.002 0.973 –1.80 –0.066 0.308 b beta sig
185.0 0.041 0.609
5,629.6 0.134 0.053
– 4,496.8 – 0.046 0.527
– 11,616.4 – 0.135 0.063
36,846.5 0.209 0.004
- - - - - -
– 24.0 – 0.007 0.917
– 697.8 – 0.008 0.911
6,767.2 0.282 0.000
Constant 39.95 - - 0.018 50.36 - - 0.002 - 21,949.2 - - 0.210
R2 0.399 0.441 0.163
N 191 191 191
figure im5

Regressions of Sentencing Severity (Months in Prison) and Lawyer’s Fees on Social Class Background, Offense Convicted of, Criminal Performance, Age and Other Characteristics

29 As predicted, the more serious the offense, the harsher the sentence. While the average sentence is 40 months (the constant), offenders convicted of homicide get 111 additional months; those convicted of violent crime (aggravated theft, assault and battery, etc.) get approximately 20 additional months. Do criminal courts take criminal achievement (or lack thereof) into account in their decisions? They do not seem to (p = 0.97). A “bungled” or unsuccessful criminal career is not a mitigating circumstance, and a more successful career is not an aggravating one. Having dependent children is not a mitigating circumstance (p = 0.68), nor is delinquent’s age (p = 0.71). History of imprisonment is not a significantly aggravating circumstantance (1.67 additional months in prison per prior prison term). Prior record is an important criterion in criminal court decisions to sentence the defendant to prison. But all the subjects in our study were active, persistent offenders and most had been in prison before.

30 For otherwise equivalent legal cases, class background effect on sentence severity seems slight: each next-higher echelon of the social scale (four in this study) decreases sentence by 3.5 months. Given an average prison term of 60 months, this means a marginal decrease of 5% for each echelon of the social scale. However, the cumulative impact amounts to a 20% disparity in sentencing severity for cases located at the bottom and top of our social scale. This gap amounts to a sizeable “discount” of minus one year behind bars.

31 What happens if we take into account offender’s ability to hire a private lawyer and spend “what it takes”? Those who can afford a private lawyer spend $5,000 in lawyer fees for each additional month of prison sentence (b = 0.22, p < .002). Obviously defense attorneys are unlikely to be the cause of sharper court severity. We therefore interpret this positive relationship as indicating that the stronger the evidence against the defendant, the more costly the defense. Is it rational for offenders to invest in such conspicuous expenditure? It would seem to be. For those in a position to take this option, each echelon of their social class background reduces that sentence by nearly six months (b = –5.8, p < 0.03). Sentence disparity between offenders located at the bottom of the social scale and those at the top is 28 months (5.8 months x 4). Since average sentence is 60 months, delinquents from the most privileged social classes seem to get their sentences reduced by a third (5.8 x 4/60 months) as a result of being represented by private lawyers. Since they have spent on average $33,000 in attorneys’ fees (see Table 4), we can assume that a year less in prison is worth $16,500.

32 Which offenders can hire a private defense lawyer? The third model in Table 5 analyzes what factors predict the amount of money defendants invest in legal representation. The finding is that the more successful offenders are in their criminal activities, the more money they spend on lawyers committed to their interests (p < .01). Criminal earning is the strongest predictor of legal ressources invested (beta = .28). Social class background also has an effect: offenders pay approximately $5,600 more in defense lawyer fees at each echelon of the social ladder (b = 5,630, p = 0.02). This is a remarkable effect. On the one hand, social class background influences delinquent performance and it is precisely this monetary “success” that enables them to hire a private lawyer. On the other hand, the indirect effect is accompanied by a direct one: offenders from relatively privileged social backgrounds are more inclined to pay whatever it takes to successfully “negotiate” a lower sentence, regardless of their criminal income. Family financial support operates in all social classes, but with each echelon, family wealth obviously increases, as well as money available for legal defense.

33 When charged with murder or manslaughter, all defendants, regardless of class background, tend to hire a private defense lawyer, even if this means going into debt. Since our sample includes offenders convicted of homicide at all social scale echelons, the fact that they all find money for legal defense partially scrambles or undermines disparity effects imputable to delinquent’s background. This explains why that disparity is much less pronounced in Table 4’s bivariate analyses than in the multivariate analyses in Table 5.

34 Cuin (1993: 44) argued that American sociologists’ academic interest in measuring social mobility rates between 1945 and 1970 was primarily driven by the three main illusions of the “American dream”; namely the “classless society,” “equal opportunity,” and “social success.” It seemed natural in this context to formulate the hypothesis that criminal trajectories would fit the dynamic of real or hoped for “upward social mobility.” As belief in the American dream waned, the focus of contemporary criminal sociology (Shapiro 1985; Albonetti 1999; Weisburd, Waring and Wheeler 1990 in the United States; Hagan and Parker 1995 in Canada; Lascoumes 1997 in France) was restricted to white-collar crime. Sociologists lost interest in the questions of unequal crime opportunities (mentoring, for example; Morselli, Tremblay and McCarthy 2006) and distribution of episodic or cumulative success in criminal trajectories (Tremblay and Morselli 2000). The analytic strategy adopted in this article steers clear of vague categorizations (e.g., “crime propensity”) and fascination with first causes ( “explaining causes of juvenile delinquency”). Our focus here is not delinquency but criminal achievement. Inequalities in criminal performance are likely to be somewhat irrelevant where occasional offenders are involved but they are a key concern for persistent offenders willing to “pay the price.”

35 English-language criminology, primarily American, has, with a few notable exceptions (Hagan 1992), banished “class effects” from its vocabulary. Self-report surveys of crime (most of which focus on juvenile delinquency) suggest that social class has no direct impact on participation frequency or even the seriousness of criminal behavior (Tittle, Villemez and Smith 1978; Tittle and Meier 1990). Any class effect is explained away as exclusion or discrimination practiced by public institutions and the ampliflying effects of social regulation mechanisms (Bernburg and Krohn 2003). This understanding seems incomplete. The fact is that offenders’ social class background may determine their chances of succeeding in their criminal activities as well as their ability to negotiate the penal repercussions of those activities.

36 Findings reported in this study are not consistent with prior research. Social class has a direct and positive effect on criminal achievement among offenders engaged in common street crimes. Sons of well-off fathers are more likely to succeed in crime, more ambitious, more likely to seek and find criminal mentors; those mentors are more likely to improve their protegés’ chances of succeeding by facilitating access to entrepreneurial crime (rather than “employee” or “appropriation” crime). These conclusions do not exclude the scenario that successful delinquent trajectories may coincide with an upward social mobility pattern (as suggested in Merton’s theory). But this eventuality should be theorized rather than derived a priori from an implicit social mobility assumption. Social class origin also impacts on offenders’ ability to negotiate legal adversity advantageously. Privileged social background increases their motivation to fight back, to hire private lawyers to defend their interests; second, it indirectly increases (i.e., through higher criminal earnings) their ability to invest the considerable sums required to get “full” legal defense. We have seen that the services offered by private lawyers to their most wealthy clients are significant: the disparity in sentence lengths for defendants at the bottom and top of the social ladder, for equivalent offenses and other characteristics, amounts to a sentence length reduction of one-third. Past sentencing research suggest that lawyers objectively work against their clients’ interests (Blumberg 1967) or that they offer no particular advantage (Nardulli 1986). But no such study has simultaneously taken into account defendants’ legal expenses (for a counter example see Feeley 1979), social class backgrounds and relative success in criminal pursuits. It is reasonable to conclude that studying the micro-dynamics of penal or legal inequalities requires examining the aims of delinquent behavior and the results delinquents manage to obtain (Cusson 1981). Still, the immediate or remote causes of the successes and failures that punctuate delinquency trajectories also have to be explicitly examined.

APPENDIX. – Nature of Jobs by Respondent’s Parents’ Social Position (s)

Liberal
professions,
executives and
managers
N Technical,
sales and services
N Skilled manual N Unskilled manual
and jobless
N
Administrator 1 Paramedic 2 Butcher 3 Bricklayer 1
Businessman 3 Artist 1 Foreman 6 Lumberjack 2
Business owner 2 Barman 1 Head of
window-washing
company
1 Truckdriver 14
Accountant 1 Tradesman 3 Construction
company owner
1 Chauffeur 6
Management
consultant
1 Transport
commission
employee
1 Cleaning company
employee
2 Roofer 1
Industrial designer 1 Broker 1 Contractor 3 Cook 1
Director of an
aviation company
1 Insurance broker 1 Electrician 6 Docker 4
Newspaper
executive
1 Canadian army 1 Building
entrepreneur
1 Mover 1
Management
(defense
department)
1 Operations manager 1 Furs, tanning 1 Newspaper
distributer
1
Company CEO 4 Shop manager 5 Building inspector 1 Warehouse worker 1
Engineer 3 Computer technician 1 Mechanic 8 Farmer 1
Justice of the Peace 1 Buyer 1 Carpenter 2 Day laborer 11
Chemist 1 Mail Clerk 1 Military personnel 3 Dairyman 1
College teacher 1 Church minister 1 Papermaker 1 Delivery 1
Teacher 1 Police officer 1 Plumber 5 Machine operator 1
Total 23 Brewery owner 1 Pyrotechnician 1 Miner 5
Nightclub owner 1 Sawmill worker 1 Machine operator 3
Gas station owner 1 Locksmith 1 Factory worker 10
Sales representative 2 Welder 3 Fisherman 1
Copyright
management
company
1 Tailor 1 Painter 2
Salesperson 4 Glazier 1 Carpetlayer 1
Total 32 Car mechanic 1 Taxi driver 3
Craft (embroidery) 1 Thief 1
Municipal employee 2 Waitress 4
Total 56 Grocery clerk 1
Unemployed 6
Total 84
figure im6

APPENDIX. – Nature of Jobs by Respondent’s Parents’ Social Position (s)

Notes

  • [*]
    Our thanks to the Revue Française de Sociologie reading committee and to Fabien Jobard and Laurent Mucchielli for their comments.
  • [1]
    Canadian federal prisons only admit delinquents with sentences over two years, but sentence reductions in the form of conditional release mean that half of convicts serve only half their prison sentence.
  • [2]
    Some interviews (n = 16, or the missing 6%) were conducted in a maximum-security prison where all inmates had to take a battery of tests and questionnaires to determine what penitentiary corresponded best to their “profile.” That context did not lend itself to relaxed interviewing so we stopped conducting interviews there.
  • [3]
    35% of detainees were not available for interviewing at the time they were called (primarily because they were assigned to kitchen or laundry duty, shop time, or had exit permits). 80% of inmates met with agreed to participate in the study.
  • [4]
    The notion of “delinquent activity” refers here to the entire range of criminal activities whose primary aim is financial gain. Since our analysis is also attentive to differences in gain by delinquent’s social class, we excluded delinquents whose criminal history showed no potentially “gainful” offenses.
  • [5]
    None of the fraudulent practices or thefts committed by delinquents in our sample amounted to business crime. On “ordinary” fraud that anyone can practice on the conventional job market regardless of job (or lack thereof), see Tremblay (1986) and Mativat and Tremblay (1997).
  • [6]
    Data from Statistics Canada (based on the 2001 census) do not allow for varying age span specifications (45 to 70, for example); the only two possible age spans were 25-54 and 55 and over. Given sample respondents’ average age (35), the second age span seemed the relevant one.
  • [7]
    Variance analyses show that average occupational ratings for the jobs held during the analysis period by delinquents in our sample do not differ by delinquent’s social background.
  • [8]
    On the other hand, proportion having spent time in juvenile detention homes was lower at the top of the social scale than the bottom: 35% for delinquents from privileged backgrounds; 38% for middle-class delinquents; 52% for unskilled workers’ sons.
  • [9]
    The procedure for estimating potential licit earnings is derived from a regression equation whose terms are 1) hourly wage; 2) weekly hours worked; 3) number of months in the job; 4) educational level; 5) social class background; 6) incarceration history; 7) age. The first stage was to calculate the coefficient of each parameter for delinquents who had in fact worked during the analysis period. This first equation made it possible to measure the contribution of each term to observed legitimate income. The second stage was to adjust the income of delinquents who had worked. We took average hourly wage for the job or jobs held during the period and readjusted weekly hours to 40 for those working fewer hours. We then readjusted to 36 the number of months worked. The other variables (social class, education and incarceration history) were multiplied by first equation coefficients. Potential income thus amounts to expected income if delinquents had held their jobs full time. To estimate unemployed delinquents’ potential income we used workers’ average hourly wage and adjusted number of hours and months accordingly. We then weighted the estimate by respondent’s education level, social class and incarceration history. The potential income regression equation is Log 10 (y) = 3.30 + 0.021 (hourly wage) + 0.005 (hours worked) + 0.034 (months in the job) + 0.013 (education level) + 0.006 (social class background) + – 0.0156 (prior prison stays) + –0.002 (age).
  • [10]
    By “entrepreneurial delinquency” we mean criminal activity areas akin to legitimate service businesses. The category includes illicit substance distribution, contreband (e.g., cigarettes), loansharking, pimping, sale of stolen goods. We distinguish “entrepreneurial” from “employee” delinquency, which refers to the activities of executants paid by or at the bidding of criminal entrepreneurs. The activity areas in the “employee” category are retail sale of illicit substances (primarily cannabis and cocaine) and car theft for resale. We also distinguish entrepreneurial crimes from “acquisitive,” “predatory” or “freelance” offenses, which refer to the activities of small “independent” delinquent groups operating on the fringes of illegal service businesses and practicing “appropriation offenses” by choice or necessity. In this area of activity we include aggravated theft, theft, burglary, fraud and confidence games of all sorts. There were no business criminals in our sample.
  • [11]
    Pires’ doctoral thesis (1983: 101) is based on 25 interviews with delinquents, most of whom were serving a prison sentence. His aim was to examine the impact of social class background on penal stigmatization by controlling for type of delinquency (business or ordinary crime). His type 1 cases were petty and mid-level bourgeoisie practicing business crime (n = 5); type 2 cases, economically insecure proletarians practicing common offenses (n = 9); type 3 cases, young bourgeois men practicing common offenses (n = 4); type 5 cases, skilled workers’ sons practicing common offenses (n = 3); type 6 cases, educated but economically insecure sons of mid-level executives and skilled employees practicing business crime (n = 4).
English

The monthly licit and illicit income of 195 offenders was reconstructed for the three-year period prior to their imprisonment. Our thesis here is that social class background increases one’s chances of succeeding in illicit activities and tends to decrease the severity of the criminal courts. The results of this study offer a new perspective on social stratification and criminal opportunity and call into question the understanding, widespread among criminologists, that social class has minimal impact on criminal trajectories.

REFERENCES

  • Online Adler, P. A. 1993. Wheeling and Dealing: Ethnography of an Upper-Level Drugdealing and Smuggling Community. New York, NY: Columbia University Press [2nd ed.].
  • Online Adler, P. A., and P. Adler. 1983. “Shifts and Oscillations in Deviant Careers: The Case of Upper-Level Drug Dealers and Smugglers.” Social Problems 31 (2): 195-207.
  • Online Albonetti, C. A. 1987. “Prosecutorial Discretion: The Effects of Uncertainty.” Law and Society Review 21 (2): 291-312.
  • Online — 1999. “The Avoidance of Punishment: A Legal-Bureaucratic Model of Suspended Sentence in Federal White Collar Cases Prior to the Federal Guidelines.” Social Forces 78 (1): 303-329.
  • Aubusson de Cavarlay, B. 1985. “Hommes, peines et infractions. La légalité de l’inégalité.” L’Année Sociologique 35: 275-309.
  • — 1987. Filières pénales. Paris: CESDIP.
  • Aubusson de Cavarlay, B.; M.-S. Huré, V. Aillet, and M.-D. Barré, collabs. 1995. Arrestations, classements, déferrements, jugements. Suivi d’une cohorte d’affaires pénales de la police à la justice. Guyancourt: CESDIP (Études et données pénales, 72).
  • Bell, D. 1965. The End of Ideology. On the Exhaustion of Political Ideas in 1950. New York, NY: Free Press.
  • Online Bernburg, J. G., and M. D. Krohn. 2003. “Labeling, Life Chances, and Adult Crime: The Direct and Indirect Effects of Official Intervention in Adolescence on Crime in Early Adulthood.” Criminology 41 (4): 1287-1318.
  • Black, D. 1976. The Behaviour of Law. New York, NY: Academic Press.
  • — 1989. Sociological Justice. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
  • Online Blishen, B. R. 1958. “The Construction and Use of an Occupationnal Class Scale.” The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science 24 (4): 519-531.
  • Online Blumberg, A. S. 1967. “The Practice of Law as Confidence Game: Organizational Cooptation of a Profession.” Law and Society Review 1 (2): 15-41.
  • Blumstein, A., J. Cohen, J. Roth, and C. Visher. 1986. Criminal Careers and Career Criminals. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.
  • Bonger, W. 1916. Crime and Economic Conditions. Boston, MA: Little, Brown.
  • Online Bradburn, N. M., J. R. Lance, and S. K. Shevell. 1987. “Answering Autobiographical Questions: The Impact of Memory and Inference on Surveys.” Science 23 (6): 157-161.
  • Chaiken, J. M., and M. R. Chaiken. 1982. Varieties of Criminal Behaviour. Santa Monica, CA: Rand Corporation.
  • Online Charest, M. 2004. “Peut-on se fier aux délinquants pour estimer leurs revenus criminels?” Criminologie 37 (2): 63-87.
  • — 2007. Classe sociale et réussite criminelle. Thèse de doctorat. Montréal: École de criminologie, Université de Montréal.
  • Online Cloward, R. A. 1959. “Illegitimate Means, Anomie, and Deviant Behaviour.” American Sociological Review 24 (2): 164-176.
  • Cuin, C.-H. 1993. Les sociologues et la mobilité sociale. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
  • Cusson, M. 1981. Délinquants, pourquoi? Montréal: Hurtubise.
  • — 1983. Le contrôle social du crime. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
  • Dubar, C., and P. Tripier. 2005. La sociologie des professions. Paris: Armand Colin.
  • Online Feeley, M. 1979. The Process is the Punishment: Handling Cases in a Lower Criminal Court. New York, NY: Basic Books.
  • Online Freedman, D., A. Thornton, D. Camburn, D. Alwin, and L. Young-DeMarco. 1988. “The Life Course Calendar: A Technique for Collecting Retrospective Data.” Sociological Methodology 18: 37-68.
  • Online Grasmick, H. G., D. Jacobs, and C. B. Mc Collom. 1983. “Social Class and Social Control: An Application of Deterrence Theory.” Social Forces 62 (2): 359-374.
  • Online Greenberg, D. 1977. “Delinquency and the Age Structure of Society.” Contemporary Crises 1: 189-223.
  • Online Hagan, J. 1992. “The Poverty of a Classless Criminology. The American Society of Criminology 1991 Presidential Address.” Criminology 30 (2): 1-19.
  • Online Hagan, J., A. R. Gillis, and J. Simpson. 1985. “The Class Structure of Gender and Delinquency: Toward a Power-Control Theory of Common Delinquent Behaviour.” American Journal of Sociology 90 (6): 1151-1178.
  • Online Hagan, J., and P. Parker. 1985. “White-Collar Crime and Punishment: The Class Structure and Legal Sanctioning of Securities Violations.” American Sociological Review 50 (3): 302-316.
  • Herpin, J. 1977. L’application de la loi. Deux poids, deux mesures. Paris: Le Seuil.
  • Hobbs, D. 1995. Professional Criminals. Brookfield, CT: Dartmouth Publishing.
  • Online Holtzman, H. R. 1983. “The Serious Habitual Property Offender as ‘Moonlighter’: An Empirical Study of Labor Force Participation Among Robbers and Burglars.” The Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology 73: 1774-1992.
  • Online Horney, J., D. W. Osgood, and I. H. Marshall. 1995. “Criminal Careers in the Short-Term: Intra-Individual Variability in Crime and its Relation to Local Life Circumstances.” American Sociological Review 60 (5): 655-673.
  • Online Hyman, H. H. 1965. “Classe sociale et système de valeurs: contribution psychologique à l’analyse de la stratification.” In Le vocabulaire des sciences sociales. R. Boudon, P. Lazarsfeld, eds. Paris: Mouton: 255-259.
  • Katz, J. 1988. Seductions of Crime. New York, NY: Basic Books.
  • Lascoumes, P. 1997. Élites irrégulières: essai sur la délinquance d’affaires. Paris: Gallimard.
  • Online Mativat, F., and P. Tremblay. 1997. “Counterfeiting Credit Cards: Displacements Effects, Suitable Offenders and Crime Wave Patterns.” British Journal of Criminology 37 (2): 165-183.
  • Online Matsueda, R. L., R. Gartner, I. Piliavin, and M. Polakowski. 1992. “The Prestige of Criminal and Conventional Occupations: A Subcultural Model of Criminal Activity.” American Sociological Review 57 (6): 752-770.
  • Online McCarthy, B., and J. Hagan. 2001. “When Crime Pays: Capital, Competence, and Criminal Success.” Social Forces 79 (3): 1035-1059.
  • — 2004. “L’argent change tout: les revenus personnels des adolescents et leur penchant à la délinquance.” Criminologie 37 (2): 123-150.
  • Online Merton, R. 1965. “Anomie, Anomia and Social Interaction: Contexts in Deviant Behaviour.” In Anomie and Deviant Behavior. M. B. Clinard, ed. New York, NY: The Free Press of Glencoe: 213-242.
  • Online Morselli, C., and P. Tremblay. 2004. “Délinquance, performance et capital social: une théorie sociologique.” Criminologie 37 (2): 89-122.
  • Online Morselli, C., P. Tremblay, and B. McCarthy. 2006. “Mentors and Criminal Achievement.” Criminology 44 (1): 17-43.
  • Online Nakao, K., and J. Treas. 1994. “Updating Occupational Prestige and Socioeconomic Scores: How the New Measures Measure up.” Sociological Methodology 24: 1-72.
  • Nardulli, P. 1986. “Insider Justice: Defense Attorneys and the Handling of Felony Case.” Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology 77 (2): 379-418.
  • Peterson, M. A., and H. B. Braiker. 1981. Who Commits Crime: A Survey of Prison Inmates. Cambridge, MA: Oelgeschlager, Gunn and Hain.
  • Online Pires, A. A. 1983. Stigmate pénal et trajectoire sociale. Thèse de doctorat. Montréal: École de criminologie, Université de Montréal.
  • Online Pires, A. A., P. Landreville, and V. Blankevoort. 1981. “Système pénal et trajectoire sociale.” Déviance et Société 5 (4): 319-345.
  • Online Preble, E., and J. J. Casey. 1969. “Taking Care of Business: The Heroin Users’ Life on the Streets.” International Journal of the Addictions 4: 1-24.
  • Online Rebellon, C. J., and M. Manasse. 2004. “Do ‘Bad Boys’ Really Get the Girls? Delinquency as a Cause and Consequence of Dating Behavior Among Adolescent.” Justice Quarterly 21 (2): 355-389.
  • Online Reiss, A. J., and A. L. Rhodes. 1961. “The Distribution of Juvenile Delinquency in the Social Structure.” American Sociological Review 26 (5): 720-732.
  • Robitaille, C. 2004. “À qui profite le crime? Les facteurs individuels de la réussite criminelle.” Criminologie 37 (2): 33-62.
  • Online Roché, S. 2001. La délinquance des jeunes: les 13-19 ans racontent leurs délits. Paris: Le Seuil.
  • Shapiro, S. P. 1985. “The Road Not Taken: The Elusive Path to Criminal Prosecution for White-Collar Offenders.” Law and Society Review 19 (2): 179-218.
  • Sutherland, E. H. 1937. The Professional Thief. Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.
  • Sutherland, E. H., and D. R. Cressey. 1966. Principes de criminologie. Paris: Cujas.
  • Sykes, G. 1958. The Society of Captives. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  • Online Tiberghien, G. 1984. Initiation à la psychophysique. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
  • Online Tittle, C. R., and R. F. Meier. 1990. “Specifying the SES/Delinquency Relationship.” Criminology 28 (2): 271-300.
  • Tittle, C. R., W. J. Villemez, and D. A. Smith. 1978. “The Myth of Social Class and Criminality: An Empirical Assessment of the Empirical Evidence.” American Sociological Review 43 (5): 643-656.
  • Online Tremblay, P. 1986. “Designing Crime. The Short Life Expectancy and the Workings of a Recent Wave of Credit Card Bank Frauds.” British Journal of Criminology 26 (3): 234-253.
  • Online Tremblay, P., and C. Morselli. 2000. “Patterns in Criminal Achievement: Wilson and Abrahamse Revisited.” Criminology 38 (2): 633-657.
  • Online Weisburd, D., E. Waring, and S. Wheeler. 1990. “Class, Status and the Punishment of White-Collar Criminals.” Law and Social Inquiry 15 (2): 223-243.
  • Online Wright, B. R., A. Caspi, T. E. Moffitt, R. A. Miech, and P. A. Silva. 1999. “Reconsidering the Relationship Between SES and Delinquency: Causation but Not Correlation.” Criminology 37 (1): 175-194.
  • Zamble, E., and F. J. Porporino. 1988. Coping, Behavior, and Adaptation in Prison Inmates. New York, NY: Springer Verlag.
Mathieu Charest
Pierre Tremblay
This is the latest publication of the author on cairn.
This is the latest publication of the author on cairn.
Uploaded on Cairn-int.info on 03/03/2014
Cite
Distribution électronique Cairn.info pour Ophrys © Ophrys. Tous droits réservés pour tous pays. Il est interdit, sauf accord préalable et écrit de l’éditeur, de reproduire (notamment par photocopie) partiellement ou totalement le présent article, de le stocker dans une banque de données ou de le communiquer au public sous quelque forme et de quelque manière que ce soit.
keyboard_arrow_up
Chargement
Loading... Please wait